The Weapondollar-Petrodollar
Coalition The Global Political
Economy of Israel, Chapter 5 by
Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler
"I warn you, that when the princes of this world start
loving you, it means they're going to grind you up into battle
sausage."
-
Louis-Ferdinand Céline, Journey to the End of the Night
|
Although economically isolated from its neighbours in terms of
trade and investment, Israel's political economy has nevertheless been
deeply embedded in the larger saga of the Middle East. The twentieth
century, with its endless thirst for energy, made the region crucial for
its oil exports. Since the 1960s, however, oil outflows have been
complemented by the newer and more precarious movement of arms imports.
And as the 'petrodollar' earnings from oil and 'weapondollar' profits from
arms grew increasingly intertwined, there emerged in the region a pattern
of 'energy conflicts', a series of oil-related wars and revolutions which
again and again rocked the Middle East, sending shock waves throughout the
world.
Enigmas
Unfortunately, most of those who tried to understand this link
between oil and arms have willingly put themselves into the familiar
straitjacket of aggregates. The theories are numerous, but their story is
almost always about 'states', 'policy makers' and the 'national interest'.
Economists writing in this vein, such as Chan (1980) and Snider (1984),
for instance, tend to concentrate on the issue of 'recycling'. The
problem, as they see it, concerns the balance of payment. Energy crises
jack up the cost of imports for oil-consuming countries, while creating
trade surpluses and accumulated reserves for the oilproducing ones. A
relatively efficient way to 're-balance' these imbalances, they continue,
is for oil importers, mostly developed countries, to sell weapons to oil
exporters. Politically, this is easy to do. Consumers in the
arms-exporting countries don't care much since the shipments do not
require new taxes, whereas rulers in the oil-exporting countries like the
trade since it boosts their self-image and sense of security. The
resulting arms race is perhaps unpleasant, but largely unavoidable;
unless, of course, the producing countries agree to lower their oil
prices.
The same universal language dominates the 'realist' literature of
international relations. The underlying political anthropology here
portrays a menacing Hobbesian environment, with each nation seeking to
endure in a largely anarchic world. Survival and security in this context
hinge on economic prosperity, national preponderance and military prowess,
which are in turn critically dependent on the differential access to
advanced technology, raw materials, and of course energy. According to the
'materialist' strand of this literature, such as Nordlinger (1981) and
Waltz (1979), this dependency explains both why central decision makers
insist on handling raw material and oil themselves, rather than leaving
the matter to private business, and also why they seem almost
trigger-happy whenever access to such resources is threatened. True, many
conflicts cannot be easily explained by material interests. And yet even
on such occasions, argue the realists, the national interest is usually
paramount. One reason, they explain, is that the national interest could
be 'ideal' as well as 'material'. And indeed, according to Krasner (1978a:
Ch. 1), after the Second World War, U.S. state goals have become more
'ideological', emphasising broad aims such as 'competition' and 'communist
containment' over strict access to resources (see also Lipschutz 1989).
The other reason is that state officials can be wrong, misunderstand the
true nature of the situation, or they can simply miscalculate the costs
and benefits. But here too, even when policy seems 'nonlogical', the
driving force is still - as always - the national interest (Krasner 1978a:
Ch. 1).
Naturally, this type of theory can explain almost everything. The
process is simple. Take any policy, and begin by looking for materialist
explanations. If you find none, don't dismay. Look for ideal ones. And if
that too fails, there are always errors, so you can never go wrong.
Moreover, the national interest itself is a very strange concept. Since
society is full of conflict, adherents of this concept argue it represents
not the sum of individual interests, but rather the overall interest of
the nation. In the language of Stephen Krasner, it is not the 'utility of the
community' which matters, but rather the 'utility for the
community', as determined by its central decision makers (1978a:
12, original emphases). However, since the decision makers themselves
rarely agree on the matter, it is usually the researcher who ends
up deciding the national interest for them (or for the reader). And the
way this interest is phrased is often so loose, that it can be made
consistent with virtually any line of action.
Now, to be fair, other grand narratives are also vulnerable to such
ambiguities. Take the 'interest of the capitalist system', a notion often invoked
by functionalist Marxism to rationalise developments which, on surface at
least, appear contrary to the immediate interests of individual
capitalists. A typical example for this is the welfare state. On the face
of it, this institution undermines capitalist power. Yet, if we were to
push this to the 'final analysis', the conclusion would be the opposite:
by making life more bearable for the workers, the welfare state ends up
keeping capitalism as a whole viable. But is this really true? Or rather,
can we prove it is true? Another example is green-field investment.
Many Marxists consider such investment as synonymous with accumulation,
and therefore good for capitalism. But if so, is the century long shift
from building new capacity to mergers and acquisitions, illustrated in
Chapter 2, bad for capitalism? And what about a high price of oil? Or war
in the Middle East? Are they good or bad for capitalism 'as a whole'? The
truth is that these questions cannot be answered, and for a simple reason.
The 'capitalist system', much like the 'state', is an encompassing myth.
It provides the broader framework for the discussion, and therefore cannot
be simultaneously used for validating or refuting a specific hypothesis
within that discussion.
The problem is illustrated in Bromley's otherwise insightful
analysis of world oil. His conclusion in that study is that the post-war
order, and particularly the emergence of OPEC and higher prices, have in
fact helped strengthened the 'general preconditions of capitalist production' under the
overall auspices of U.S. hegemony (1991: 59). But what exactly are these
'general preconditions'? And if OPEC and the oil crisis have indeed
boosted the system of U.S.- dominated capitalism during the 1970s and
1980s, why haven't the cartel's disintegration and lower oil prices
undermined this system during the 1990s? Or have they? Surely, the world
has changed in the interim. But then, it always does, so how could we ever
know?
The international flows of oil and arms have been examined also
from the more disaggragate perspective of the underlying industries, but
here, too, there is a considerable lack of unanimity, even on substantive
issues. Writing from an implicit 'instrumentalist' view, Blair (1976) and
Engler (1977), for example, contend that, intentionally or not, the energy
policies of parent governments (particularly the United States, Great
Britain and the Netherlands) have had the effect of assisting the
international oligopoly of world oil. An almost opposite view is expressed
by Turner (1983) and Yergin (1991), who, in line with a more realist
perspective, argue that there was a gradual but systematic erosion in the
primacy of international oil companies, and that, since the 1970s, these
firms were in fact acting as 'agents', or intermediaries between their
host and parent governments. Studies on the international arms trade have
been equally controversial. According to Sampson (1977), the absence of
any international consensus on disarmament created a void, which was then
filled by the persistent sales effort of the large weapon makers. And
since arms exports become particularly significant in peacetime as
domestic defence budgets tend to drop, the end of U.S. involvement in
Vietnam during the early 1970s redirected attention to the Middle East,
causing military shipments into the region to rise. Other writers,
however, such as Krause (1992), reject this interpretation. The impact of
private producers on arms sales policies, he claims, should not be
overstated, at least not in the case of the United States, where the
volume of arms exports is small relative to domestic military procurement
and the contractors' civilian sales.
Whatever their insight, though, most writers tend to treat Middle
East conflicts and energy crises as related though distinct
phenomena. Wars are commonly seen as arising from a combination of local
conflicts complicated by superpower interactions. Energy crises, on the
other hand, are generally perceived as a consequence of changing global
market conditions and institutional arrangements (such as OPEC). Some
conflicts - for instance, the 1990-91 war between Iraq and the U.S.-led
coalition - have been partly attributed to a struggle over the control of
crude reserves, whereas others - specifically the Arab-Israeli wars of
1967 and 1973, and the Iran-Iraq conflict of 1980-88 - were seen as having
aggravated ongoing energy crises. Yet, no one has so far offered a general
explanation of 'energy conflicts' - that is, a framework which would
integrate militarisation and conflict on the one hand, with global
energy flows and oil prices on the other. Most significantly, existing
writings on both oil and war in the region tend to deal rather
inadequately, and often not at all, with the process which matters the
most, namely the accumulation of capital.
As outlined in Chapter 2, during the 1970s and early 1980s the
pendulum of differential accumulation swung from breadth to depth. While
economic growth and corporate amalgamation receded, stagflation rose to
fill the gap, contributing massively to the differential profit of
dominant capital (Figures 2.6 and 2.9). A central facet of this new regime
was the cycle of militarisation and energy conflicts in the Middle East,
which helped both fuel inflation and aggravate stagnation the world over
(Figure 2.10). Stated in this way, our argument may sound reminiscent of
supply-shock theory, but the similarity is only superficial. For one,
stagflation started to pick up in the early 1970s, before the
increase in the price of oil. The oil boom certainly fuelled the process,
but as a mechanism, not a cause. Second, and more importantly, to argue
that oil prices were somehow a shock coming from 'outside' the system is
to miss the point altogether. On the contrary, if there was indeed any
'system' here, it was one of differential accumulation. And at that
particular historical junction, its engine was running in depth mode
fuelled by an atmosphere of crisis emanating from the Middle East. In
other words, the region was very much an integral part of the 'system'.
The purpose in this chapter is to examine the global political
economy of this process. In a nutshell, our argument is that, during the
1970s, there was a growing convergence of interests between the world's
leading petroleum and armament corporations. Following rising nationalism
and heightened industry competition during the 1950s and 1960s, the major
international oil companies lost some of their earlier autonomy in the
Middle East. At the same time, the region was penetrated by large U.S. and
European-based manufacturing companies which, faced with mounting global
competition in civilian markets, increased their reliance on military
contracts and arms exports. The attendant politicisation of oil,
together with the parallel commercialisation of arms exports,
helped shape an uneasy Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition between
these companies, making their differential profitability increasingly
dependent on Middle East energy conflicts. Interestingly, when we look at
the history of the region from this particular perspective, the lines
separating state from capital, foreign policy from corporate strategy, and
territorial conquest from differential profit, no longer seem very solid.
Many conventional wisdoms are put on their head. State policies,
ostensibly aimed at advancing the national interest, often appear to
undermine it; company officers and government officials, moving through a
perpetually revolving door, sometimes simultaneously cater to several
masters; arms races are fuelled for the sake of 'stability'; and peace is
avoided for being 'too expensive'. In contrast to these anomalies, the
logic of differential accumulation seems remarkably robust. It helps us
make sense of corporate strategies, of foreign policies and of the link
between them - and all of that within the broader context of 'energy
conflicts'.
The Military
Bias
The first half of the nineteenth century in Europe was marked by
rising hopes for progress. The Industrial Revolution was helping humanity
harness nature. The French Revolution brought new ideas of freedom.
Nationalism, liberalism and socialism were breaking new ground. And
absolutism was on its way out. With these changes all taking place at
once, many were tempted to believe that society was on its way to a better
future, one in which military conflict and war were to be rooted out. The
theoretical justification for these hopes owed much to the technological
determinism of French philosopher Auguste Comte. War he argued, was mainly
the consequence of scarcity. Scarcity, however, was alleviated by
industrialisation and technical progress, and since these were expected to
continue their forward march, conflict and war were bound for extinction.
And initially, he seemed vindicated. The 'bellicosity index', devised by
Pitirum Sorokin and charted in Figure 5.1, shows the intensity of
European military conflicts, measured by a weighted average of various
indicators, as it evolved since the twelfth century (Sorokin 1962,
reported in Wright 1964: 56). This intensity roughly doubled every hundred
years until the seventeenth century. During the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries, however, with technical change and industrialisation picking up
speed, bellicosity fell sharply, much along the lines suggested by Comte.
And yet, the drop proved a false start. By the second half of the
nineteenth century, with the European powers scrambling to complete their
colonial acquisitions, conflict again flared up in and outside the
Continent. Sorokin's bellicosity index came back with a vengeance, soaring
to record highs in the twentieth century, even without counting the Second
World War and beyond. Comte was wrong. Industrialisation in general and
capitalism in particular were compatible with war after all. And indeed,
by the early twentieth century, a growing number of writers, mostly
Marxist, started pondering the link between capitalism and imperialism.
Figure 5.1 European Bellicosity
Index *
-
- * Number of wars weighted by duration, size of fighting
force, number of casualties, number of countries involved, and
proportion of combatants to total population
SOURCE: Sorokin (1962) reported in Wright (1964: 56).
Imperialism
The seminal study on the issue, titled Imperialism, was
written by a British left liberal, John Hobson (1902). Many of his themes
have resurfaced again and again in subsequent works, so the argument is
worth presenting, if only briefly. During the latter part of the
nineteenth century, capitalism in the leading countries was moving from
atomistic competition toward concentration and monopoly. According to
Hobson, this transition tended to redistribute income from wages to
profits, thus creating a chronic problem of 'oversavings' and
'underconsumption'. Monopoly profit, like any profit, was earmarked for
greenfield investment. With workers having less to spend, however, the
need for such investment was much reduced. In order to avoid stagnation
and crisis, the excess savings therefore had to find outlets
outside the home country, hence the tendency toward imperialist
expansion. The scramble for colonies was intense, and Africa, which in
1875 had only 10% of its territory colonised, lost another 80% to European
powers within the next quarter of a century. And, yet, this was only
ironic, since, according to Hobson, imperialism was in fact a net
loss to society, and even to its capitalist class. A more sensible
route would have been to redistribute income back from monopoly profit to
wages, thereby reversing the entire causal chain from monopolisation to
stagnation. So why had imperialism prevailed over redistribution? For
Hobson, the reason was that state policy was conducted not by society at
large, and not even by the capitalist class, but rather by a fairly narrow
coalition for whom imperialism was indeed hugely profitable. The main
profiteers were the arms producers, trading houses, the military and
imperial apparatus, and above all, the financiers, whose foreign
investments appreciated greatly from reduced risk premiums brought by
imperial rule. The financiers, leading the pro-imperial coalition, were
able to harness key politicians to their cause, enlist the possessing
classes on threat of redistribution at home, and have the newspapers
inflame for them the necessary atmosphere of nationalism and racism.
Marxists writers were greatly influenced by Hobson, although most
tended to reject his belief that capitalism could be 'reformed'. According
to Rosa Luxemburg, territorial expansion and takeover - in quest for both
new markets and cheaper inputs - was in fact inherent in
capitalism, 'the first mode of economy which is unable to exist by itself,
which needs other economic systems as a medium and soil' (1913: 467).
Moreover, the expansion was necessarily violent. 'Force is the only solution
open to capital: the accumulation of capital, seen as a historical
process, employs force as a permanent weapon, not only as its genesis, but
further on down to the present day' (p. 371).
And indeed, according to Rudulf Hilferding (1910), imperialism
projected its violence inward as much as outward, working to transform the
economic, political and ideological face of the imperial countries
themselves. In contrast to the classical stage, in which the various
fractions of capital were politically divided, during the monopoly stage
the leading elements among these fractions were fused into 'Finance
Capital', an amalgamate of industry and finance controlled by the big
banks. This newly welded power, argued Hilferding, drove finance capital
into seeking an ever growing territory for its operations, but such
expansion was meaningless unless protected by tariffs against outside
competition. It was here, then, in the dual quest for territory and
protection, that private capital discovered it actually needed a strong
state:
"The demand for
an expansionary policy revolutionizes the whole world view of the
bourgeoisie, which ceases to be peace-loving and humanitarian. The old
free traders believed in free trade not only as the best economic policy
but also as the beginning of an era of peace. Finance capital abandoned
this belief long ago. It has no faith in the harmony of capitalist
interests, and knows well that competition is becoming increasingly a
political power struggle. The ideal of peace has lost its luster, and in
place of the idea of humanity there emerges the glorification of the
greatness of and power of the state... The ideal now is to secure for
one's own nation the domination of the world, an aspiration which is as
unbounded as the capitalist lust for profit from which it springs....
Since the subjection of foreign nations takes place by force - that is, in
a perfectly natural way - it appears to the ruling nation that this
domination is due to some special natural qualities, in short to its
racial characteristics. Thus there emerges a racist ideology, cloaked in
the garb of natural science, a justification for finance capital's lust
for power, which is thus shown to have the specificity and necessity of a
natural phenomenon. An oligarchic ideal of domination has replaced the
democratic ideal of equality" (Hilferding 1910: 335)
For Karl Kautsky, a Marxist contemporary of Hilferding, this
portrayal was far too bleak. The conflict between industrial and financial
capital, he argued, had not been decisively won by finance capital as
Hilferding claimed. In fact, there was scope for labour opposition, in
both the developed and periphery countries, to strengthen the hands of the
industrial fraction. Such opposition, if successful, could redirect
capitalism toward a more benign alternative, which Kautsky called
'ultra-imperialism' (1970; originally published in 1914). Exploitation
would surely continue, but the exploiters, instead of locking horns in
imperial destruction and inter-capitalist war, would vie for a common
front. 'Hence, from a
purely economic standpoint', he wrote, 'it is not impossible that
capitalism may still live through another phase, the translation of
cartelisation into foreign policy: a phase of ultra-imperialism,
which of course we must struggle against as energetically as we do against
imperialism, but whose perils lie in another direction, not in that of the
arms race and the threat to world peace' (p. 46, original
emphasis).
With hindsight, we can read here an early anticipation of the
transnational corporation, of decolonisation, and of the shifting emphasis
of imperialism from inter-capitalist rivalry to core-periphery struggles.
But when Kautsky first articulated this view, before the First World War,
he was greeted by great hostility from Lenin and Bukharin. Lenin in
particular, having thrown his hopes on an imminent revolution, refused to
see capitalism as culminating in anything less than Armageddon. Unequal
development among the different capitalist powers, he argued, prevented
any mutual cooperation among them:
"Finance capital
and the trusts do not diminish but increase the differences in the rate of
growth of the various parts of the world economy. Once the relation of
forces is changed, what other solution of the contradictions can be found
under capitalism than that of force?" (Lenin 1917:
243-4; cited from Marxist Archives).
Furthermore, if workers were sufficiently powerful to bend finance
capital as Kautsky suggested, what was to prevent them from moving all the
way to socialism?
Military
Spending
After the Second World War, things changed drastically. In the
periphery, colonialismcam e to an end, while in the developed core
countries real wages soared and unemployment fell sharply. Was this a
fundamental change, asked the Marxists? Was capitalismfinally able,
perhaps with the aid of government intervention, to resolve its earlier
contradictions? And if so, was socialism irrelevant? According to
contemporary adherents of the 'monopoly capital school', led by Baran and
Sweezy, the answer to all three questions was negative. The post-war
prosperity was certainly real; but it wasn't because of capitalism, but
despite capitalism. The shift from small-scale production to big
business, they argued, altered the functioning of the economy in two
important respects. On the production side, large-scale undertakings,
heavy R&D spending, and the incessant introduction of new technologies
enabled the big oligopolies to cut cost as never before. At the same time,
the strong oligopoly bias against price competition not only prevented
these cost savings from being translated into lower prices, but actually
introduced persistent inflation. And so, contrary to the view of classical
Marxism, monopoly capitalism, by lowering cost and raising prices, created
a tendency for the surplus to rise. For Marx, the chief menace to
capitalism came from a rising organic composition of capital, leading to a
tendency for the rate of profit to fall; here, on the other hand, the key
issue was the rising rate of exploitation, or 'surplus' in the new
terminology. But if so, what was the problem? Indeed, shouldn't a rising
surplus bring higher profit, thus boosting capitalismeven further?
Not necessarily, argued Baran and Sweezy:
"According to
our model, the growth of monopoly generates a strong tendency for surplus
to rise without at the same time providing adequate mechanisms of surplus
absorption. But surplus that is not absorbed is also surplus that is not
produced: it is merely potential surplus, and it leaves its statistical
trace not in the figures of profits and investment but rather in the
figures of unemployment and unutilised productive capacity" (Baran
and Sweezy 1966: 218)
In short, Hobson's curse was still with us. Monopoly bred
redistribution, underconsumption, and therefore falling surplus -
that is, unless absorbed by external offsets to savings. Contrary
to the early writings on the subject, however, the most potent offsets
according to Baran and Sweezy were created not by colonial expansion, but
through the 'institutionalised waste' of state spending, a process first
identified by Thorstein Veblen.
For external offsets to savings to be effective, the two writers
argued, they needed, first, to absorb more surplus than they generated,
and, second, to be available in large doses. Investment was no good here,
since it usually generated more surplus than it absorbed, while exports
were limited by foreign demand. Government expenditures, on the other
hand, and particularly military spending, faced neither limitation.
They were commonly 'wasteful' in the sense of absorbing but not generating
surplus, and they could be extended almost at will. Technically speaking,
civilian government spending could work in much the same way.
Politically, though, it was unwelcome. The main reason was that such
spending, as it pushed the economy toward full employment, undermined the
social hegemony of business. According to Michal Kalecki,
"'discipline in
the factories' and 'political stability' are more appreciated by the
business leaders than profits. Their class instinct tells themthat lasting
full employment is unsound from their point of view and that unemployment
is an integral part of the normal capitalist system.... The workers would
'get out of hand,' and the 'captains of industry' would be anxious to
'teach them a lesson'.... In this situation a powerful block is likely to
be formed between big business and the rentier interests, and they
would probably find more than one economist to declare that the situation
was manifestly unsound. The pressure of all these forces, and in
particular of big business would most probably induce the Government to
return to the orthodox policy of cutting down the budget deficit. A slump
would follow in which Government spending policy would come again into its
own" (Kalecki 1943b: 141, 144)
Military spending did not pose a similar threat. It did not compete
directly with private interests, and while it might have lessened the
disciplinary impact of unemployment, the 'shortfall' was more than
compensated for by the direct use of force and violence in the name
national security. And so, capitalism, according to Kalecki, tended to
oscillate between two ideal types. One extreme was a democratic model in
which the government, torn between supporting and legitimising
accumulation, ended up creating a 'political business cycle' by its
stop-go policies. The other extreme was the fascist model, in which full
employment was sustained by military spending in preparation for war, and
where the concentration camp substituted for unemployment as a way of
pacifying workers.
Since the Second World War, argued Baran and Sweezy, the United
States used armaments to write its own ticket to prosperity. According to
Gold (1977), the arrangement was supported by a powerful 'Keynesian
Coalition' between big business and the large unions, which, since the
1950s, consistently preferred 'military Keynesianism' and aggressive
foreign policy to the more benign use of civilian spending. And the policy
was not without consequences. Ten years before the publication of Baran
and Sweezy's Monopoly Capital, Shigeto Tsuru, a Japanese political
economist, wrote an article entitled 'Has Capitalism Changed' (Tsuru
1956). Having examined the sources and offsets of U.S. savings, his
conclusion was that in order to maintain its prevailing growth rate, the
country needed military spending equivalent to roughly 10% of its GDP.
However, if this proportion was to be maintained, he continued, the
absolute level of military expenditures ten years down the road
would become far too high to justify for a country in peace. And indeed, a
decade later, in 1966, the United States was deeply involved in the
Vietnam War, with military spending kept at close to 9% of GDP.
The U.S.
Arma-Core
The 'Angry
Elements'
During the 1970s, other writers, such as O'Connor (1973) and
Griffin, Devine and Wallace (1982), have taken the argument a step
further, suggesting that government involvement, and particularly military
spending, were affected not by overall macroeconomic needs or the interest
of capitalists in general, but rather by the specific requirements of
dominant economic groups. More significantly, however, the Korean and
Vietnam conflicts of the 1950s and 1960s indicated that military spending
was not only a consequence of economic structure, but also an
important force shaping that structure. One of the first writers to
recognise this double-sided relationship was Michal Kalecki. Much of his
early writings from the 1930s and 1940s were concerned with the effect on
macroeconomic performance of the 'degree of monopoly' in the underlying
industries. Toward the end of his life, during the 1960s, he closed the
circle, pointing to the way in which macroeconomic policy, primarily
military spending, could affect the economic and social structure. In his
articles 'The Fascism of Our Times' (1964) and 'Vietnam and U.S. Big
Business' (1967), Kalecki claimed that continued U.S. involvement in
Vietnam would increase the dichotomy between the 'old', largely civilian
industries located mainly on the East Coast, and the 'new' business
groups, primarily the arms producers of the West Coast. The rise in
military budgets, he predicted, would effect a redistribution of income
from the old to the new groups. The 'angry elements' within the U.S.
ruling class would be significantly strengthened, pushing for a more
aggressive foreign policy, and propagating further what Melman (1974)
would later call the 'permanent war economy'.
Was Kalecki right? Had the epicentre of the U.S. 'big economy', or
dominant capital in our language, indeed shifted from 'civilian' to
'military' oriented corporations? Unfortunately, the question is not easy
to answer. Corporate power, we argue in this book, is a matter of
differential profit. And, yet, the link between profit and production is
elusive at best. If military contractors were producing only armaments and
civilian firms only non-military items, the problem would have been less
serious. But that is not the case in practice. Since the 1960s, most large
U.S. firms have become conglomerates to a greater or lesser extent, with
military contractors diversifying into civilian business and vice versa.
The difficulty for our purpose is that conglomerate finance is inherently
'contaminated' by intra-firm transfer pricing, so although we may know how
much a firm gets from the Pentagon in sales revenues, we cannot
know for sure the impact this has on its profit.
The problem, though, is not insurmountable. In what follows, we
identify the leading 'Arma-Core' of the U.S. economy, defined as the inner
corporate cluster which appropriated the lion's share of defence-related
contracts, and which was highly dependent on such contracts. Having
identified the members of this 'Arma-Core', we then proceed to examine
their combined profit relative to U.S. dominant capital as a whole. Now,
although both groups derived their earnings fromm ilitary as well as
civilian business, and although the impact on their profit of each line of
business cannot be determined with accuracy, it is safe to assume that the
Arma-Core's profitability was much more sensitive to military contracts
than that of dominant capital as a whole. A rise in the profit share of
the Arma-Core would then indicate that Kalecki was right, and that the
'military bias' of the United States indeed enhanced the power of
'military oriented' firms. A decline in the ratio would of course suggest
the opposite.
Who then was in the Arma-Core? A first approximation could be
derived from data published by the U.S. Department of Defense (DoD), in
its annual listing for the 100 Companies Receiving the Largest Dollar
Volume of Prime Contract Awards [1
footnote]. From this publication we can learn that military
procurement was fairly concentrated, such that, over the period between
1966 and 1991, the largest 100 contractors accounted for between 62 and
72% of the DoD's total prime contract awards. However, it is probably
inappropriate to consider all of the leading 100 firms as members of the
Arma-Core. Our tentative criterion for inclusion in this core is for the
firm to be large enough to exercise political leverage, as well as
significantly dependent on defence contracts, and not all of the leading
100 companies fit both characteristics. Some corporations - such as
AT&T, IBM, ITT, Eastman Kodak, Ford, Chrysler, Exxon, Mobil and Texaco
- were very large but depended only marginally on military contracts.
Others, like Singer, Teledyne, E-Systems, Loral, FMC, Harsco and Gencorp,
relied more heavily on defence sales, but were probably not big enough to
exercise political leverage. Thus, concentrating only on large,
defence-dependent contractors, we end up with a more limited group of
about 20 to 25 firms, which for our purpose here comprise the U.S.
Arma-Core.
The precise choice of boundary between the Arma-Core and the
remaining contractors is of course arbitrary to some extent, a problem
which is further exacerbated by periodic changes in the ranking of firms.
Given the attendant uncertainty and ambiguity, we focus on a more limited
sample of only 16 corporations. These include, in alphabetical order:
Boeing, General Dynamics, General Electric, Grumman, Honeywell, Litton
Industries, Lockheed, McDonnell Douglas, Martin Marietta, Northrop,
Raytheon, Rockwell International, Texas Instruments, Textron, United
Technologies, and Westinghouse. This group is representative of the
Arma-Core in that it consists of only large firms and, with only minor
exceptions, it included the top ten DoD contractors in every year between
1966 and 1991.[2
footnote] During the 1966-91 period, these 16 firms received more
domestic military contracts than any other comparable group of American
corporations. On average, they accounted for 36% of the DoD's total prime
contract awards, with a floor of 30 per cent (in 1966) and a ceiling of
41% (in 1985). As a group, the Arma-Core proved much more dependent on
sales to the Pentagon than dominant capital as whole. For the latter,
denoted here by the Fortune 500, military contracts ranged between 5 and
10% of total sales. The comparable figure for the Arma-Core was 20 to 40%
(Nitzan and Bichler 1995: 460-1).
Turning to the crucial question of differential profitability,
Figure 5.2 presents the net profit share of the Arma-Core within dominant
capital. The data show that, following the Vietnam War, this share had
doubled to 10% by the mid-1980s, up from 5% in the mid-1960s. In other
words, if our interpretation here is correct, the 'permanent war economy'
which existed in the United States pretty much until the end of Reagan's
second presidency, seems to have indeed created an ongoing 'military bias'
within the U.S. corporate sector, strengthening the relative power of
military contractors. Kalecki was certainly prescient.
Figure 5.2 The Rise of the U.S.
Arma-Core
SOURCE: Fortune; Standard & Poor's Compustat.
Corporate
Restructuring and 'Military Keynesianism'
To a certain extent, this interaction between military expenditures
and business realignment was also part of a broader, worldwide
transformation affecting the relationships between nation states and
transnational corporations. Following the Second World War, the global
economic significance of the United States began to wane. The decline is
evident in various indicators. For instance, whereas during the 1960s U.S.
GDP measured one and half times the combined total for the EEC's 12
countries plus Japan, by the early 1990s the ratio was only half as large.
Also, as the country grew more economically open, its trade balance moved
from surplus to deficit, requiring increasing doses of capital inflows to
cover the shortfall. Under these circumstances, with the local market
becoming relatively less important as well as increasingly contested by
foreign competitors, U.S.-based firms naturally looked for further
opportunities abroad. And indeed, by the early 1990s, roughly 25% of their
profits came from outside the country, up from less than 10% in the 1960s.
The foreign challenge, however, remained gruelling, and Americanbased
firms continued their slide down the global rankings. In contrast to 1960,
when the United States was home to 114 of the world's 174 largest firms,
by the 1990 the number dropped to a mere 56 (figures in this paragraph are
calculated from U.S. Department of Commerce through McGraw-Hill Online,
and from Franko 1991).
These major transformations affected the choice of both corporate
strategy and economic policy. Faced with mounting competitive pressures in
civilian markets, many large U.S.-based firms found themselves
increasingly drawn into the shelter of high-profit government contracts,
particularly in areas such as defence, nuclear energy, space, and medical
technology.[3
footnote] On the policy side, this dependency got the U.S.
administration entangled in a commitment to 'military Keynesianism',
which, paradoxically, grew deeper as the big corporations became more
global in scope. The reason was that, with a rising share of corporate
profits coming from abroad, domestic government policies affected a
diminishing portion of corporate earnings. Or to put it somewhat
differently, all other things being equal, a given increase in the
companies' overall profit required a larger increment of domestic military
contracts. Under these circumstances, any attempt to eliminate the
'military bias' spelled a major blow to the credibility of macroeconomic
policy, and of course serious injury to some of the country's most
powerful firms.
Relying on domestic military spending, however, was always a tricky
business. The main problem is the mismatch existing between the
requirements of arms making and the reality of arms selling.
From an industrial standpoint, the technology-intensive nature of weapon
making requires continuous research and development and open production
lines. Furthermore, military production is highly specialised, so it
cannot be easily converted into civilian use when demand for weapons
slackens. These industrial considerations call for a stable growth in
demand for arms - and yet, that is not what usually happens in the
armament business. Perceived as a drain on the country's resources,
military expenditures need to be legitimised by external threats, and
these tend to fluctuate with the ups and downs of international politics
and the frequency of armed conflicts. The consequence is to make domestic
weapon procurement inherently unstable, which is of course a
serious headache for the large armament producers. Clearly, if these firms
are to keep their production lines open, they can never rely solely on
domestic procurement, and must constantly look for 'counter-cyclical'
export markets.
Arms Exports
The perils of restricted demand are hardly new, of course. For
example, during the Seven-Year War Frederick the Great found himself
forced to import 32,000 rifles from abroad, and that because only a few
years earlier he decided to cut down production capacity for lack of
domestic demand (Frederick the Great 1979: 18). The simplest solution for
this dilemma would have been to supplement the home market with foreign
sales, but, initially, that was not at all obvious and for a very simple
reason: weapons were usually produced by the state whose officials were
hardly keen on selling them to potential enemies. Industrial advancement,
however, increasingly shifted armament production into private hands, and
it was this privatisation which eventually enabled the business to become
truly international. The imperative of combining private ownership and
foreign sales was succinctly elucidated in 1913, when, on the eve of the
First World War, Krupp, the German weapon maker, got entangled in a
corruption scandal. Answering his critics in the Reichstag, the Minister
of War, Josias von Heeringen, defended this new system, arguing that in
order to maintain sufficient capacity for wartime, military producers had
to export in peacetime. This, he insisted, could be achieved only by
private firms which were free from the patriotic scruples of state
companies (Sampson 1977: 43). And indeed, by the end of the nineteenth
century, the large armament firms - such as Krupp, Nobel, Armstrong,
Vickers, Du-Pont, Electric Boat and Carnegie - were all privately owned,
highly dependent on foreign markets, and most importantly, unregulated
(ibid., Chs 2-4).
This structure of the military industry first came under scrutiny
during the 1920s and 1930s. After the First World War, the League of
Nations accused the arms companies of fermenting international conflict,
causing a flurry of official investigations into the arms business.
Following the Nye Committee hearings in the United States, the
isolationist congress passed the 1935 Neutrality Bill, with special
provision for a National Munitions Control Board to supervise American
arms exports. A few years later, the 1941 Lend Lease Act brought the U.S.
government further into the centre-stage of the arms trade, and by the end
of the Second World War it was commonly accepted that the export of
weapons was no longer a private affair, but rather a matter of foreign
policy.
After the war, the 'Truman Doctrine' conceived military exports,
particularly to Europe, as part of the larger effort to contain communism,
a goal which would be later extended to legitimise arms shipments to South
East Asia. Yet this new emphasis on broader policy goals did little to
resolve the problem of unstable demand. The continued military
Keynesianism of the 1950s and 1960s created the basis for an Arma-Core of
large military-dependent firms, and by the late 1960s, toward the end of
the United States' direct involvement in Vietnam, these corporations
appeared just as vulnerable to budget cuts as the Carnegies and Du-Ponts
half a century earlier. Despite several decades of change, the weapon
business remained predominantly private, and with the war effort now
receding, its owners were once again seeking to counteract excess capacity
with foreign military sales.
Arms Exports
and Corporate Profit
Interestingly, until the late 1980s most observers tended to doubt
this 'economic' rationale for U.S. military exports. Such exports, they
argued, were simply too small to make a difference (for instance, Krause
1992: 106). And on the surface they seemed to have a point. Domestic
procurements, measured in constant 1995 prices, ranged from $61 billion in
1974, after the end of the Vietnam conflict, to $136 billion in 1987, at
the peak of the Reagan build-up. The comparable figures for foreign
military sales were much smaller: between $5 billion in 1963, just before
the Vietnam conflict started to pick up, and $23 billion in 1987, at the
height of the Iran-Iraq War (data sources in Figure 5.3). And yet the
comparison is deceiving. The arms makers, like any other capitalist, are
concerned not with sales but with profits, and these tend to be far
higher in export sales. The basic reason is simple enough. The production
of weapons, particularly major platforms such as tanks, aircraft and
ships, involves very high research and development outlays. This fixed
component is typically recovered through domestic sales, so by the time
the company starts exporting, its average unit cost is far lower, and the
profit per unit correspondingly higher. And indeed, an internal DoD study
cited in Brzoska and Ohlson (1987: 120) estimated foreign military sales
to be 2.5 times more profitable that those made to the U.S. government,
while similar ratios - ranging from 2 to 2.3 - emerged from other industry
sources (U.S. Congress 1991: 53).
Using these profitability indicators in conjunction with sales
data, Figure 5.3 reassesses the relative importance of arms
exports. The top series in the chart traces the value of domestic military
shipments, measured in constant prices. The bottom series imputes the
relative contribution of foreign military sales to overall
military-related profit (domestic as well as foreign). The later
computation is based on the conservative assumption that the export markup
was twice as high as the local one, and that the ratio between the two
markups remained stable over time.[4
footnote] Now, since actual markups do change over time, the ratio
plotted in the chart is necessarily imprecise. Nevertheless, its overall
magnitude and broad trajectory are telling. All in all, the chart
suggests, first, that arms exports were probably far more important for
U.S. military contractors than is commonly assumed, and, second, that this
dependency has grown over time. Export first became significant during the
military build-down of the late 1960s and early 1970s. The United States
was scaling back its direct involvement in Vietnam, and with military
exports to the region continuing to rise, the ratio of export profit to
total profit soared. Based on our imputation, in 1973, at the cyclical
peak of the process, foreign sales accounted for up to one-third of all
military-related profit. Subsequently, with President Carter reversing the
spending downtrend, and with the Reagan Administration embarking on the
country's largest military build-up in peacetime, arms exports became
relatively less important. And yet, even in the late 1980s, when domestic
spending reached record highs, exports still accounted for a sizeable
one-quarter of all military-related profit. Ominously, during the 1990s,
with military spending dropping and 'peace dividends' mushrooming the
world over, foreign military sales have become the profit life-line of
U.S.-based contractors, accounting for an estimated 45% of their total
military-related earnings.
This focus on profit rather than sales helps explain why a single
export deal can sometimes make or break even a large contractor. Grumman,
for example, was saved fromnear-bankruptcy in 1974 by the sale of F-14
Tomcat fighter planes to Iran (Sampson 1977: 249-56). Similarly, during
the early 1990s, the sale of 72 F-15 Eagle fighters to Saudi Arabia gave
financially troubled McDonnell Douglas a temporary lease on life
(Business Week, 16 March 1992; Fortune, 22 February 1993).
Northrop, on the other hand, was seriously hampered by its F- 20 debacle,
a dedicated 'fighter for export' which the company spent $1.4 billion to
develop but never managed to sell (Ferrari et al. 1987: 27).
Contrary to received wisdom, then, the evidence, however tentative,
suggests that the Arma-Core was in fact very much affected by U.S.
military exports. And given the growing political leverage of this core,
it should be hardly surprising that foreign policy has become increasingly
bound up with private profit.
Figure 5.3 U.S. Military
Business: Domestic and Foreign
SOURCE: U.S. Arms Controls and Disarmament Agency (Annual); U.S.
Department of Commerce through McGraw-Hill (Online).
Commercialising Arms Exports: From Aid to Sales
The growing interaction between trade and the flag in this area was
facilitated by two related developments. The first of these developments
was the commercialisation of arms exports. During the 1950s, when
arms exports were still seen as a matter of foreign policy, up to 95% of
U.S. foreign military deliveries were financed by government aid. Over
time, though, with the line separating state from capital becoming less
and less clear, the proportions changed, and by the 1990s only 30% were
given as aid. The rest, up to 70%, were now paid for directly by the buyer
(figures computed from U.S. Defense Security Assistance Agency 1989; 1992;
and U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of the Census Annual).
The second development, which greatly facilitated this
commercialisation, was the emergence of the Middle East as the world's
prime destination for exported arms. The process, illustrated in Table
5.1, shows the level of arms imports from all sources (expressed in
1987 prices), as well as their regional distribution during four distinct
periods. During the first period, between 1963 and 1964, global arms
imports amounted to $11.7 billion annually, with about half going to
Europe (earlier data are unavailable). In the aftermath of the Second
World War, the Continent was still perceived as potentially unstable, and
so until the mid-1960s, the United States sent most of its military
assistance to its NATO allies primarily in the form of surplus stockpile
grants. Since 1965, however, the emphasis began to change. The 'hot spot'
of the West-East conflict moved to South East Asia, and with it came a
rapid escalation in the global armament trade. Over the 1965-73 period,
world arms import rose by 65 per cent, to an annual average of $19.4
billion - with over one-third now going to East Asia. In the United
States, the shift of focus from Europe to the outlying areas of the Third
World brought a redefinition of arms-export policies. Weapon deliveries to
Vietnam and other South East Asian countries were still financed by aid,
but the European countries were now increasingly requested to pay for
their U.S.-made hardware.
Table 5.1 Arms Imports by Region
(annual averages)
SOURCE: Original current-price data are from U.S. Arms Control and
Disarmament Agency (Annual). [Because of repeated updates, data are from
the last annual publication in which they appear.] Implicit GDP Deflator
is from Economic Report of the President (Annual).
This change, which signalled a return to the pre-war commercial
pattern of weapon sales, was to some extent inescapable. The post-war
policy of containing communism through military aid was feasible as long
as U.S. arms shipments were small and U.S. government finances solid. But
as the arms race started picking up and the federal deficit ballooned,
successive American administrations began to preach the merits of
commercial sales. During the Eisenhower, Kennedy and Johnson governments,
the trend was limited mainly to transactions with NATO, but the late-1960s
entanglement in Vietnam hastened the final policy reversal. By 1969, the
new 'Nixon Doctrine' stipulated that all transfers of weapons - including
those going to the Third World - should, whenever possible, depend not on
direct U.S. military involvement, but on the buyer's ability to pay.
Global
Redistribution and the Rise of the Middle East
The single most important factor enabling this shift from aid to
sales was the global income redistribution triggered by the 1973 oil
crisis. The explosive growth of OPEC's revenues made the cartel's members
ideal clients for weaponry, and in 1974, after the U.S. exit from Vietnam,
the Middle East became the world's largest importer of armaments. As
Table 5.1 shows, over the 1974-84 period, the annual arms trade
rose to nearly $46 billion, up 136 % from the previous period, with
roughly 53% of the total going to the Middle East and Africa (mainly Libya
and Egypt). The pivotal role here of global redistribution can hardly be
overstated. Indeed, as oil revenues dropped during the latter half of the
1980s, the rapid rise in arms transfers was arrested. During 1985-89,
world military imports rose only marginally, to an average annual level of
$51 billion, with much of the stagnation taking place in the Middle East
and Africa, whose combined share dropped to 42%. (During the 1990s, the
global redistribution of income has taken a new turn with the rapid growth
of 'emerging markets' in Latin America, South Asia and South East Asia.
Interestingly, this shift has been accompanied by a 'mini-boom' of
military imports flowing into their regions, with the initial takeoff
already evident in the increasing share of 'Others' recorded in Table
5.1)
To sum up, the post-war era was marked by several important changes
affecting the nature of arms production and trade. In the United States,
there emerged an Arma-Core of large defence contractors, whose rising
power, particularly since the Vietnam conflict, enabled it to appropriate
a growing share of the profit of dominant capital. The relative growth of
these companies was influenced by the continuous 'military bias' of the
U.S. economy, which was itself partly the consequence of mounting global
competition in civilian markets. The consolidation of this powerful group
of firms strengthened their political leverage - mostly in matters
affecting the domestic budget, but increasingly also in the choice of
foreign policy. This latter significance stemmed primarily from the
intrinsic dependence of arms production on flexible foreign demand. After
the Second World War, the U.S. Administration made military exports a tool
of foreign policy; but, over time, the very menu of policy options became
intertwined with the development of the Arma-Core. Initially, the need for
foreign markets was both limited and easily financed by U.S. military aid.
However, the continuous ascent of defence-dependent corporations
eventually raised arms exports up to a level which could no longer be
backed solely by U.S.-government grants. The dilemma was solved by a
gradual return to the pre-war pattern of commercial trade in weaponry, and
what made this transition feasible was the global redistribution of income
triggered by the Middle East oil crisis.
With this latter development, the U.S. Arma-Core found itself
entering the centre-stage of Middle Eastern 'energy conflicts'. The
consequences of this entry were far reaching. The large defence
contractors which earlier depended mainly on the level of domestic
military spending and foreign military aid, now found their financial fate
increasingly correlated with the boomand bust of the oil business. And
they were not alone. With themon the same stage were also the newly
empowered OPEC governments, the governments of the imperilled Western
countries, and the major petroleum companies whose dominant position in
the oil world was now called into question. The emergence of the Middle
East as the 'hot spot' of world conflict and the leading arms-importing
region has altered the delicate relationships between these transnational
corporations and both their parent and host governments. Furthermore, the
seemingly circular sequence of regional wars and oil crises brought the
petroleumcom panies into a new, and in some way unexpected alliance with
the arms makers. Before we can turn to examine this alliance, however, we
must look more closely at the changing circumstances affecting the
petroleumindustry.
Middle East Oil
and the Petro-Core
The 'Demise
Thesis'
The dominant view among students of the subject, is that the oil
crisis of the 1970s signalled the final stage in a fundamental
transformation, a transformation which started in the 1950s, and which
eventually altered the structure of the oil industry. The first aspect of
this transformation was the relative decline of the major oil companies
vis-à-vis a growing number of lesser firms. After the Second World War,
the 'Seven Sisters' - notably Exxon (then Standard Oil of New Jersey),
Royal Dutch/Shell, British Petroleum (previously Anglo-Iranian), Texaco,
Mobil, Chevron (then Socal) and Gulf - still dominated the relatively
concentrated international oil arena. Gradually, however, the entrance of
smaller independent companies, the growth of existing firms other than the
seven largest, and the re-entry of the Soviet Union into Western energy
markets, made the sector less concentrated, eroding the leading position
of the oil majors. In just two decades, between 1953 and 1972, the share
of the 'Seven Sisters' in the oil industry outside the United States fell
from 64% to 24 % of all concession areas; from 92 to 67% of proven
reserves; from 87 to 71% of production; from 73 to 49% of refining
capacity; from 29 to 19% of tanker capacity; and from 72 to 54% in product
marketing (Jacoby 1974: Table 9.12, p. 211).
A second and perhaps more important facet of this transformation
was that the locus of control, which previously rested with the owners and
officers of the large petroleum companies, had now apparently shifted into
the hands of government officials, monarchs and dictators. At the
'upstream' part of the industry, the oil companies succumbed to the
relentless nationalistic pressure of their host countries, and after a
quarter-century of eroding autonomy eventually surrendered most of their
crude oil concessions. Once begun, the transition was swift and decisive.
The transnational companies, which as late as 1970 still owned about 90%
of all crude petroleum produced in the non-communist world, found their
equity share drop sharply to only 37 per cent by 1982, most of it now
concentrated in North America (figures cited in Penrose 1987: 15). A
similar change occurred at the 'downstream' segment of the industry,
particularly in the Western industrial countries. With the oil crisis, the
cost of energy and its very availability became major policy issues with
wide-ranging domestic and foreign implications; so that here, too, the
firms found they had to comply with political dictates - in this case,
those coming from their own parent governments. Energy in general and
petroleum in particular became political questions, and just 'as war was too important to
be left for the generals', wrote Yergin (1991: 613), 'so oil was clearly too
important to be left to the oil men'.
And so emerged the 'demise thesis'. According to Turner (1983:
118-24), after the Second World War the major oil companies have come to
assume various roles, acting as 'governmental agents', as 'transmission
belts' between host and parent governments, as occasional 'instigators',
or simply as a 'complicating factor' - but, in his opinion, all of these
roles have merely added some colour to the sphere of international
political economy. In the final analysis, he argues, it was the diplomats
who were making the crucial decisions. The multinational petroleum
companies - particularly after the oil crisis - have been pushed aside,
reduced to a status of 'interested bystanders' in the high politics of
world oil (pp. 147-8).
Whither the
Oil Companies?
At the time, the 'demise thesis' seemed persuasive, even
fashionable. It was certainly the next logical step in a long theoretical
sequence, which began with the 'bureaucratic revolution' of the 1930s,
continued through the 'managerial revolution' of the 1940s, and from there
led to the 'technostructure' of the 1950s and 1960s, and to 'statism' in
the 1970s. There was only one little problem. The evidence used to support
this thesis was strangely silent on the issue which mattered most, namely
the accumulation of capital. In the final analysis, capitalism emerged and
expanded not because it offered a new ethos, but because that ethos helped
the rising bourgeoisie alter the distribution of income from landed rent
to business profit. For that reason, those who argue in favour of
bureaucratic-statist determinism, or believe in the demise of big
business, must go to the essence of capitalism and demonstrate that these
developments have fundamentally altered the distribution of income and the
mechanism of accumulation.
In this particular case, if we are to conclude that the oil majors
have indeed declined, we need to be first shown not only that they lost
market shares and became dependent on government policies, but also that
these structural and institutional changes affected their business
performance, and, specifically, their profits. Assuming that the
large petroleum companies were squeezed between rising competition and
more demanding governments, the combined pressure must have caused their
net earnings to wither - either absolutely, or at least relative to some
broader aggregates. And yet, this has never been demonstrated in the
literature. Most studies pertaining to the 'multinational debate' in the
energy sector either gloss over the issue, or simply ignore it altogether;
and even where profits are referred to, the data are often incomplete and
rarely analysed in a wider historical context. [5
footnote] Unfortunately, this neglect helps distort the overall
picture, for while the institutional and structural indicators may imply
that the major oil companies have indeed declined, the profit data seem to
suggest the exact opposite!
Table 5.2 The Petro-Core:
Differential Profitability Indicators (annual averages, %)
SOURCE: Net profit and rate of return on equity of the Petro-Core
are from O'Connor (1962), Fortune directories and Standard &
Poor's Compustat. Net profit of all U.S. corporations is from U.S.
Department of Commerce through McGraw-Hill (Online), and from U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Statistical
Abstract of the United States (1992), Table 871, p. 542. Net profit
and rate of return on equity for the Fortune 500 are from various 'The
Fortune 500' listings. Net profits and rate of return on equity for the
world's 40-42 leading petroleum firms are from Carl H. Pforzheimer &
Co., Comparative Oil Company Statements, reported in the
Statistical Abstract of the United States (Annual).
Table 5.2 provides some long-term summary indices for the
profit performance of the world's six largest petroleum companies in the
early 1990s. This group - which we label here the 'Petro-Core' - consists
of the original 'Seven Sisters', with the exception of Gulf which was
acquired by Chevron in 1984. The comparison includes various differential
accumulation indicators, relating the profit performance of the Petro-Core
to corresponding figures for larger corporate groupings, including a wider
international composite of petroleum firms, the Fortune 500, and the U.S.
corporate sector as a whole.
The first column gives the average net rate of return for the
Petro-Core (ratio of net profit to owners' equity). The overall impression
from these data is that the oil crises of the 1970s and early 1980s in
fact helped boost the profitability of the large oil companies, a
notion to which we return later in the chapter. For our purpose here,
though, the more interesting results are those obtained from the
differential indices. In the second column, we present the rate-of-return
ratio between the Petro-Core and the 'Petroleum 40-42' group of companies.
This ratio is calculated by dividing the net rate of profit on equity
obtained in the Petro-Core, by the matching rate attained by the Petroleum
40-42 - the latter being a broader cluster of the world's 40-42 largest
non-governmental petroleum companies (including the Petro-Core firms). The
results show that, during the late 1960s and 1970s, despite the
competitive assaults from new entrants, the Petro-Core was able to
maintain its net rate of return more or less in line with the other oil
companies, and that during the 1980s it actually succeeded in surpassing
them. A similar result is obtained in the third column, where we compare
the net rate of return for the Petro-Core with that of U.S. dominant
capital as a whole, approximated by the Fortune 500. Here, too, the large
Petro-Core firms exhibit a remarkable staying power, even after the 'OPEC
revolution' and the politicisation of oil in the industrialised countries.
Indeed, despite the wholesale surrendering of concessions, the revoking of
preferential U.S. foreign tax-credits, and a list of other adverse
consequences of the new oil order, the Petro-Core's rates of return in the
1970s, 1980s and early 1990s were higher than the comparable averages for
U.S. dominant capital as a whole.
Another way to assess the differential earning power of the large
oil companies is by looking at their relative share in the profit of a
wider aggregate of companies. This we do in the last three columns, where
we compute the share of the Petro-Core in the net profits of the
Petroleum40-42 group, the 'Fortune 502' (as defined below), and all
U.S.-based corporations. Beginning with the first of these net-profit
ratios (fourth column), we can see that despite the Core's relative
decline in terms of economic activity (such as concessions, reserves,
production, refining, transportation and marketing), its distributive
share of the industry's net profit did not decrease at all. If we consider
the world's largest 40-42 petroleum companies as a reasonable proxy for
the international non-governmental petroleum industry, then it appears
that the share of the Petro-Core in global oil profit in fact rose - from
around three-fifths during the late 1960 and 1970s, to almost
three-quarters by the 1980s, and then further, reaching close to
four-fifths by the early 1990s. A similar picture emerges when we examine
the share of the Petro-Core in the net profit of U.S. dominant capital
(fifth column). Taking the Fortune 500 group again as our tentative proxy
for U.S. dominant capital, and adding to its ranks the European-based
British Petroleum and Royal Dutch/Shell, we can see that the profit
position of the large Petro-Core firms within this modified 'Fortune 502'
group has remained surprisingly unassailable. Here we have a longer time
series, extending from 1954 to 1991, so the comparison is even more
telling. During the late 1950s, when the oil majors were still the
undisputed leaders of the international oil industry, the Petro-Core
accounted for nearly one-fifth of the net profits earned by the Fortune
502 group, but that has hardly changed in the subsequent period when these
firms presumably lost their pre-eminence to new entrants and politicians.
The final indication for the enduring power of the Petro-Core is given by
their net-profit ratio with the U.S. corporate sector as a whole - an
index for which data are available since 1930 (sixth column).
Following the Achnacarry and Red Line agreements of 1928, in which
the large international oil companies divided the world and the Middle
East between them, the Petro-Core became so powerful that, even with the
Great Depression and collapsing raw material prices, it still managed to
appropriate over 9 per cent of all net profits earned by U.S.
corporations. The economic revival of the Second World War raised overall
corporate profits, thus causing this net-profit ratio to drop
significantly. However, during the 1950s, the ratio began to climb again,
rising more or less continuously until, in the 1980s, it topped 10 per
cent - more than the earlier record of the 1930s.
Clearly, then, as we move from means to end - that is, from
economic activity to differential profitability - the historical picture
seems to change, and rather significantly. What appears as the
Petro-Core's relative decline from the viewpoint of exploration,
production, refining and marketing, is not at all what we see when we
reach the 'bottom line'. On the contrary, once we focus on the ultimate
business criteria of differential accumulation, the oil crisis seems to
turn from a menace to a blessing. The Petro-Core, far from losing ground,
has actually held and even consolidated its leading position - relative to
other international oil firms, relative to the U.S. big economy, and
relative to the U.S. corporate sector as a whole.
Now, these findings are admittedly puzzling. After all, competitive
pressures from new entrants and demands from governments did increase
since the 1950s, so how did the Petro-Core manage to nevertheless come on
top with such a feat of differential accumulation? Alternatively, given
the Petro-Core's remarkable staying power, why did it give up so much
control to governments? The paradox, though, is only apparent, and
disappears quickly once we shift our attention from the industry's
formal institutions to its effective power structure. The
1970s indeed altered the formal control of oil. But following the line of
analysis first anticipated in the wake of the crisis by Blair (1976), and
recently summarised by Bromley (1991), one may argue that the ultimate
consequence of this transformation was to consolidate rather than
undermine the relative earning power of the large petroleum companies.
Politicising
Oil: From 'Free Flow' to 'Limited Flow'
Perhaps the most fundamental aspect of this transformation was the
progressive politicisation of the oil business. [6
footnote] While this process was to a large extent continuous, it
is nevertheless possible to distinguish between two qualitatively
different phases. The first period, roughly until the early 1970s, could
be labelled the 'free-flow' era in world oil - this in the sense that the
control of oil was exercised through private ownership with state
'interference' assuming only a secondary role (Turner 1983: Chs 2-3).
During the 1920s and 1930s, the international petroleum arena was
practically run by the large companies, particularly British Petroleum,
Royal Dutch/Shell and Exxon. In 1928, the three companies, meeting in the
Scottish castle of Achnacarry, divided the world between them. In that
year, the same firms also signed, together with other companies, the Red
Line Agreement to coordinate their activities in the Middle East. [7
footnote] Over the following three decades, explicit collusion
slowly evolved into a broader system of complex arrangements and
understandings, partly overt but mostly tacit, which together enabled the
large oil companies to maintain their control of production,
transportation, refining and marketing around the world (cf. Blair 1976:
Ch. 5). However, the Second World War and the ensuing economic boom made
things more complicated. First, the substitution of the United States for
Britain as the leading Western power shifted the internal balance among
the Seven Sisters in favour of the U.S.-based companies, undermining to
some extent the group's previous cohesion. And second, the growing number
of independent producers exerted downward pressure on prices, precisely at
a time when rising nationalism in the Middle East and Latin America called
for higher royalties. Threatened with loss of control, the large oil
companies resorted to classic predatory market practices against the
independents, but that wasn't enough. And as the problem continued, the
companies turned to their governments for help.
Government assistance, particularly in the United States, assumed a
variety of forms, including foreign tax-credits to offset royalty
payments, restrictions on the importation of cheap oil into the United
States, exemptions from antitrust prosecution, and a CIA-backed coup
against the Mossadeq government in Iran, to name a few. The fact that the
large petroleum companies were able to secure such services is of course
not entirely surprising, given their 'special relations' with successive
U.S. administrations (cf. Tanzer 1969; Engler 1977). Part of this
capital-state symbiosis was surely rooted in the strategic nature of oil.
And yet that could by no means be the whole story. The reason, on which we
shall elaborate later in the chapter, is that, on many occasions, U.S.
government actions in favour of the large oil companies were patently
contradictory to the nation's material interest. [8
footnote] Staunch realists like Stephen Krasner solved the anomaly
by blaming such policies on 'nonlogical' behaviour and the
'misconceptions' of policy makers (1978a: 13-17). But there could be a
much simpler explanation, namely that the oil companies, along with other
dominant capital groups, were increasingly seen as synonymous with the
national interest. Perhaps the best summary of this union was given by
U.S. Major-General Smedley Butler:
"I spent
thirty-three years and four months in active service as a member of our
country's most agile military force - the Marine Corps.... And during that
period I spent most of my time being a high-class muscle man for Big
Business, for Wall Street, and for the bankers. In short, I was a
racketeer for capitalism.... Thus, I helped make Mexico and especially
Tampico safe for American oil interests in 1914. I helped make Haiti and
Cuba a decent place for the National City Bank boys to collect revenues
in.... I helped purify Nicaragua for the international banking house of
Brown Brothers in 1909-1912. I brought light to the Dominican Republic for
American sugar interests in 1916. I helped make Honduras 'right' for
American fruit companies in 1903. In China in 1927 I helped see to it that
Standard Oil went its way unmolested. During those years, I had, as the
boys in the back room would say, a swell racket. I was rewarded with
honors, medals, promotion. Looking back on it, I feel I might have given
Al Capone a few hints. The best he could do was to operate his
racket in three city districts. We Marines operated on three
continents". (cited in Huberman 1936: 265-6, original
emphases)
Such blunt services, however, were too crude and certainly
insufficient for the post-colonial era. They were unsuited for the more
subtle 'new imperialism' of transnational companies, and wholly inadequate
for dealing with new problems such as business competition and the
management of technical change. Since the 1960s, therefore, there emerged
an urgent need for some 'external' force, a qualitatively new
institutional arrangement which would bring crude production back to what
the 'market can bear' - yet without implicating the oil companies as
'monopolies' and the Western governments as 'imperialists'. Historically,
this institutional arrangement appeared in the form of OPEC and the
upstream nationalisation of crude oil.
The broad causes for this transition have long been debated in the
literature, but at least one of its consequences seems fairly clear. As
Adelman (1987) rightly pointed out, the cartel achieved something which,
for political reasons, the oil companies could never have pulled off on
their own: a dramatic increase in prices. The eighteen-fold rise in
the price of crude oil between 1972 and 1982 would have been inconceivable
under the 'free-flow' system of private ownership. Rapid increases of such
magnitude required not only a tight institutional framework, but also that
oil appeared to be in short supply. The problem, though, was that oil was
hardly scarce. In fact, it was abundant. The industry was plagued by
chronic excess capacity (from the perspective of profit, that is), and the
only way to bring this back to what the market could 'bear' was through an
exogenously imposed 'crisis'. Such crisis, though, necessitates a new
political realignment, and that is precisely what happened. With the
nationalisation of crude oil, production decisions now moved to the
offices of OPEC, opening the way to a new, 'limited-flow' regime.
The 'limited-flow' era worked wonders for OPEC. There can be little
doubt about that. But the bonanza hardly came at the expense of the
Petro-Core. On the contrary, OPEC, by working closely if tacitly with the
companies, was instrumental in boosting their relative performance. The
converging interests of these two groups is clearly illustrated in
Figure 5.4, which shows a tight positive correlation between the
value of OPEC's crude oil exports on the one hand, and the net profit of
the Petro-Core on the other. A simple linear regression between the two
series suggests that for every one dollar increase or decrease in export,
there was a corresponding 6.7 cents change in the companies' net profit,
and, moreover, that changes in the value of exports accounted for almost
three-quarters of the squared variations in profits. Causality, however,
was also running in the other direction, from the companies to the
oil-producing countries. Although OPEC was providing the pretext for the
crisis, there was still the need to coordinate output - and that it
couldn't do on its own. As Blair (1976: 289-93) and Turner (1983: 90-7)
correctly indicated, managing the immense complexity of the oil arena
required an overall knowledge which OPEC lacked, and which could be
supplied only by the oil majors. The latter, of course, were no longer
controlling output directly as producers, but they were now doing so
indirectly, as the largest buyers, or 'offtakers' of crude petroleum.
Interestingly, the rationale for this new alliance was delineated already
in 1969 by the Saudi petroleum minister, Sheik Yamani. 'For our part', he
stated, 'we do not want
the majors to lose their power and be forced to abandon their role as a
buffer element between the producers and the consumers. We want the
present setup to continue as long as possible and at all costs to avoid
any disastrous clash of interests which would shake the foundations of the
whole oil industry' (cited in Barnet 1980: 61). There emerged,
then, a new and more sophisticated realignment. The oil companies have
indeed relinquished formal control, but that was largely in return for
higher profits. Perhaps the most striking expression of this new
'trade-off' was provided by British Petroleum. The 1979 revolution in Iran
deprived BP from access to 40% of its global crude supplies; yet in that
very year its profits soared by 296% - more than those of any other major
company (Turner 1983: 204; Yergin 1991: 684-7; and Fortune, 'The
Fortune 500' 1978, 1979).
Figure 5.4 OPEC and the
Petro-Core: Conflict or Convergence?
SOURCE: OPEC (Annual); Fortune
The convergence between OPEC and Western interests has long been
suspected. On the eve of the first oil crisis, for example, Dan Smith
suggested in The Economist's survey titled 'The Phony Oil Crisis'
(7 July 1973), that the U.S. Administration may have supported OPEC's
drive for higher prices as a way of slowing down the Japanese economy (see
also Anderson and Boyd 1984: Chs 9-11; and Terzian 1985: 188-202). Another
possible reason why the U.S. government 'capitulated' and accepted
separate negotiations leading to the Tehran and Tripoli Agreements of
1971, was that the large oil firms saw this as a means of checking the
ominous rise of independent companies (Blair 1976: Ch. 9). In the words of
Odell (1979: 216), the 1970s brought an 'unholy alliance' between the
large international oil companies, the United States, and OPEC, which
together sought to use higher prices as a way of boosting company profits,
undermining the growth of Japan and Europe, and fortifying the American
position in the Middle East. To these, Sampson (1977: 307) also added the
eventual support of the British government, the Texas oil lobby, the
independents, investors in alternative sources of energy, and the
conservationists - all with a clear stake in more expensive oil.
In a way, then, the oil arena has evolved in a direction opposite
to that of the armament industry. While the military sphere of domestic
spending and arms exports has been increasingly commercialised, the
petroleum industry has grown more politicised. This politicisation,
however, has by no means spelled the demise of the large oil companies. On
the contrary, it became a prerequisite for their survival. The
relentless search for new reserves, along with the incessant proliferation
of new technology created a constant menace of excess capacity and falling
prices. At the same time, with the number of actors on the scene growing
rapidly, counteracting this threat solely through corporate collusion was
impractical. For the large companies, the way to overcome these challenges
was to integrate their private interests into a broader political
framework.
The
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition and Middle East 'Energy Conflicts'
And so, toward the beginning of the 1970s, several groups of large
U.S.-based firms saw their interests converging in the Middle East. To
recap, the first of these groups included the large weapon makers of the
Arma-Core which turned to the region in search of export markets. The
second cluster comprised the leading oil companies of the Petro-Core,
including those based in Europe, which were now driven toward a broader
alliance with OPEC. These were also joined by a second tier of interested
parties, including engineering companies such as Bechtel and Fluor with
big construction projects in the oil regions, as well as large financial
institutions with an appetite for petrodollars. Each of these groups stood
to benefit from higher oil prices; and yet none could have done so on its
own. To push up the price of oil, they needed to act in concert, and this
is how a 'Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition' between them came into
being. In this section, we argue that, deliberately or not, the actions of
these groups helped perpetuate an almost stylised interaction between
energy crises and military conflicts. In this process of 'energy
conflicts', the ongoing militarisation of the Middle East and periodical
outbreaks of hostilities contributed toward an atmosphere of 'oil crisis',
leading to higher prices and rising oil exports. Revenues from these
exports then helped finance new weapon imports, thereby inducing a renewed
cycle of tension, hostilities, and, again, rising energy prices.
From Crisis
to Prices
Let's begin with prices. The common perception is that, one way or
another, the price of crude oil depends on its underlying 'scarcity'. From
this viewpoint, OPEC's early success is usually attributed to rapid
Western growth during the 1960s and 1970s. This growth, it is argued,
created 'excess demand' for oil, which in turn pushed up prices and made
the cartel easy to manage. The same process, only in reverse, is said to
have worked since the early 1980s. Lower industrial growth and improved
energy efficiency, goes the argument, created 'excess supply', causing
prices to fall and OPEC to disintegrate. Despite its popularity, however,
this framework is vulnerable to both logic and fact.
From a long-term perspective, the relevant proxy for scarcity is
the ratio of proven reserves to current production. Over the past three
decades, due to extensive exploration, this ratio rose by a quarter - from
about 30 production years in the mid-1960s, to over 40 production years
during the 1990s (data from British Petroleum Annual). Now, according to
the scarcity thesis, the increase should have brought crude oil prices
down. And yet the exact opposite has happened. As Figure 5.5 shows,
during the 1990s the real price of oil was not lower than in the 1960s,
but twice as high. Whatever the cause for the longterm price
appreciation, it was certainly not scarcity. And the concept is not
much more useful in the short term. As we explained in Chapter 2, the
argument that prices are affected by scarcity is meaningful only when such
scarcity is set by natural or technical limitations. But that is by no
means the case in the oil industry, which commonly operates well below its
technical capacity. In this context, the impact on price of a 'shortfall'
in supply is therefore a matter of sellers' collusion, not 'scarcity'.
Figure 5.5 'Scarcity' and the
Real Price of Oil
SOURCE: British Petroleum (Annual); IMF and U.S. Department of
Commerce through McGraw-Hill (Online).
The second problem with the scarcity thesis is that 'excess supply'
and 'excess demand' reflect the difference between the desires of
sellers and buyers; and desires, as we all know, cannot be directly
observed, let alone quantified. A common way to bypass the problem, if
only provisionally, is to use changes in inventories as a proxy for excess
or shortage. But then the evidence from such exercise is often more
embarrassing than revealing. The difficulty is illustrated in Figure
5.5, where we contrast the real price of crude oil (denominated in
constant 1995 dollars), with the excess of global consumption over global
production (measured as a% of the average of the two). The latter variable
reflects changes in inventories, with negative values representing
build-up and positive ones denoting depletion. Now, if excess consumption
indicates a 'shortage' (caused for example by unexpected rise in demand),
and excess production represents a 'glut' (triggered for instance by the
unforeseen arrival of 'distress oil'), then we should expect prices to
rise in the former case and fall in the latter. The facts, however, tell a
much more confused story. During the glut-plagued 1960s, the scarcity
thesis seemed to be working, with inventories building up and prices
falling. But then things started to go wrong. Although the inventory
build-up continued through much of the early 1970s, the real price of oil
soared, rising by 16% in 1971, 4% in 1972, 6% in 1973, and 228% in
1974. And indeed, according to Blair (1976: 266-8), the 1973/74 oil crisis
had nothing to do with the 'oil shortage', simply because there wasn't any
such shortage to begin with. Early in 1973, the ARAMCO partners (Exxon,
Mobil, Chevron and Texaco) were explicitly warned by the Saudis, both of
the pending Egyptian attack on Israel, and of the possibility that oil
would be used as a political weapon (see also Sampson 1975: 244-5).
Anticipating the consequences, the companies raised production in the
first three-quarters of the year, an increase which fully compensated for
the eventual drop in the last quarter. All in all, OPEC production for
1973 amounted to 11.0 billion barrels, slightly higher than the 10.8
billion it should have been based on long-term growth projections (Blair
1976: 266fn). And the law of scarcity didn't seem to work much better in
subsequent years. Between 1975 and 1980, inventories continued to
accumulate, but the real price of oil, instead of remaining the same or
falling, soared by a cumulative 135%. During the first half of the 1980s,
excess production gave way to excess consumption, and yet the real price
of oil again refused to cooperate. Instead of rising, it fell by 71%
between 1980 and 1986. Even over the past 15 years, with the oil market
presumably becoming more 'competitive' (notwithstanding the Gulf War of
1990-91), it is hard to see any clear relationship between excess demand
and real price movements.
Last but not least, there is the issue of relative magnitudes.
Indeed, even if we could ignore the direction of price movements, their
amplitude seems completely out of line with the underlying mismatch
between production and consumption. Over the past 40 years, world
consumption was usually 2-3 per cent above or below world output. But then
could such relatively insignificant discrepancies explain dramatic
real-price fluctuations of tens or sometimes hundreds of% a year? And why
are prices sometimes hyper sensitive to the mismatch, while at other times
they hardly budge?
The solution for these perplexities is to broaden the notion of
'scarcity'. As a speculative commodity, the price of crude petroleum
depends not only on the relationship between current production and
consumption, but also - and often much more so - on future
expectations. The prices buyers are willing to pay relate not only to
present energy needs and the cost of alternative sources, but also to
expected future prices. Similarly, sellers, both individually and as a
group, are constantly weighing the trade-off between present incomes and
anticipated but unknown future revenues. Moreover, these factors are not
independent of each other. Indeed, buyers' willingness to pay is often
affected by the apparent resolve of sellers; which is in turn influenced
by the extent of consumers' anxiety. Once acknowledged, such intricacies
imply that any given consumption/production ratio can be associated with a
host of different prices, depending in a rather complex way on the
nature of future expectations.
The significance of these considerations could hardly be
overstated. To illustrate, consider the fact that after the emergence of
OPEC, the number of primary industry players has grown appreciably - from
less than a dozen in the 1960s to over 150 by the late 1970s, according to
one estimate - and that still without counting governments (Odell 1979:
182). Such multiplicity should have undermined the industry's ability to
coordinate output, but that is not what the facts tell us. Indeed, if we
were to judge on the basis of OPEC's revenues and the companies' profits
as illustrated in Table 5.2 and Figure 5.4, it would appear
that collective action was indeed more effective with hundreds of
participants during the 1970s and 1980s, than with only a handful before
the onset of the crisis! The reason for this apparent anomaly is that, in
the final analysis, the price of oil - on the open market, but also
between long-term partners - depends not only on the ability to limit
current output to 'what
the market can bear', but also on the nature of perceived
scarcity associated with 'external' circumstances. And in our view, since
the early 1970s, the single most important factor shaping these
perceptions was the vulnerability of Middle East supplies.
The global importance of Middle East oil is of course hardly new,
but its significance has increased substantially since the Second World
War, and particularly since the 1960s. In 1972, on the eve of the first
oil crisis, the region accounted for as much as 36% of the world's total
production and 62 % of its proven reserves, up from 12% and 42%,
respectively, in 1948 (computed from Jacoby 1974: Table 5.1, pp. 68-9;
Table 5.2, pp. 74-5). But as they became more crucial, the region's oil
supplies were also growing more vulnerable. The oil 'prize' acted like a
magnet, turning the Middle East into an arena of superpower confrontation.
And this confrontation, combined with rising nationalism, growing class
inequalities, and the ancient tensions of ethnicity and religion, helped
stir up instability and armed conflict. The consequences for oil were
twofold. First, the region's ongoing militarisation since the late 1960s
created a constant threat for future energy supplies, helping maintain
high prices even in the absence of tight producer coordination. Second,
the occasional outbreak of a major conflict tended to trigger an
atmosphere of immediate 'energy crisis', pushing confident sellers to
charge higher prices and anxious buyers to foot up the bill. And, indeed,
since the early 1970s it was regional wars which perhaps more than
anything affected the course of oil prices. Despite the absence of any
real shortage, the onset of such hostilities - the 1973 Israeli-Arab
conflict, the 1979 Islamic Revolution in Iran, the 1980 launch of the
Iran-Iraq War, and the 1990/91 Gulf War - invariably generated an
atmosphere of 'crisis' and 'shortage', sending prices higher. Similarly,
once the crisis atmosphere dissipated - either at the end of a war, or
when conflict no longer seemed threatening to the flow of oil - prices
began to stagnate and then fall. The importance of these features is
attested by their incorporation into common jargon. The industry's 'price
consensus', for example, now customarily incorporates, in addition to its
'peacetime' base, also such items as 'embargo effects' and 'war premiums'
(Fortune, 5 November 1990). The precise magnitude of such
'premiums' and 'effects' cannot be determined, of course, but their
significance seems beyond dispute.
From Oil
Revenues to Arms Imports
The weapondollar-petrodollar link was also running in the other
direction, with rising oil exports helping finance military imports to
fuel the regional arms race. This side of the arms-oil interaction is
examined in Figure 5.6, where we contrast the annual value of
foreign arms deliveries to the Middle East, with the corresponding value
of the region's oil production three years earlier (both in constant
dollars). The reason for the lag is that current oil revenues bear on the
value of current military contracts, but the delivery of
weapons, which is what we display in the chart, usually takes place later,
with a lag of roughly three years. [9
footnote] We also express both the vertical and horizontal axes as
logarithmic scales, in order to show the 'responsiveness' of arms imports
to oil revenues. In this presentation, the slope of a trend line passing
through the data indicates the% change of arms imports corresponding, on
average, to a 1% change in oil revenues three years earlier.
Figure 5.6 Middle East Oil Income
and Arms Imports
SOURCE: British Petroleum (Annual); U.S. Arms Controls and
Disarmament Agency (Annual); U.S. Department of Commerce through
McGraw-Hill (Online).
The first thing evident from the chart is the sharp 'structural
change' affecting the relationship between the two variables. Around the
early 1970s, as the oil regime shifted from 'free flow' to 'limited flow',
the slope of the relationship tilted from a fairly steep position to a
much flatter one. During the 1964-73 period, the trend line going through
the observations had a slope of 3.3, indicating that for every 1% change
in oil revenues there was, three years later, a 3.3% increase in arms
imports. Despite this high 'responsiveness', though, the magnitudes
involved were fairly small. Both superpowers were preoccupied with Europe
and subsequently with East Asia, and since oil revenues increased only
moderately, weapon shipments into the region, although responding eagerly,
remained limited in size. By the early 1970s, however, things changed, and
rather drastically. The slope of the trend line going through the 1973-97
data fell to 0.4, meaning that a 1% rise in oil revenues during that
period generated only 0.4% increase in arms imports. And, indeed, in
contrast to the 1960s, when the region's export revenues were earmarked
largely for weapon purchases, now they were allocated also to a range of
civilian imports, as well as being accumulated as reserves in Western
banks. But, then, with the flow of oil having been 'limited' by the high
politics of government and companies, and with arms exports becoming
increasingly commercialised, the dollar value of both oil income and
military imports soared to unprecedented levels toward the early 1980s -
only to drop, again in tandem, when this order started to disintegrate
since the mid-1980s.
The second, and perhaps more remarkable thing about Figure
5.6, is the extremely tight fit between the two series. Based on this
chart, it appears that knowing the oil revenues of Middle Eastern
countries was practically all that one needed in order to predict the
overall value of arms deliveries three years later! Arms deliveries into
the region were of course affected by numerous factors, including domestic
tensions and inter-country conflicts, superpower policies to protect and
enhance their sphere of influence, and the evolution of domestic arms
production, to name a few. Furthermore, some arms deliveries were financed
by aid or loans, so their import was not directly dependent on oil
revenues. Yet, based on the chart, it would seemthat these factors were
either marginal, or themselves corollaries of the ebb and flow of the
'great prize' - oil.
From
Differential Accumulation to 'Energy Conflicts'
We have now reached the final step of our brief statistical
journey, ready to move from means to ends. Our method in this exploration
was to progressively distil the interaction between oil and arms, moving
from production, to sales, to profit, and, eventually, to the differential
accumulation of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition. The task now is to
identify the hidden links between this differential accumulation on the
one hand, and Middle Eastern 'energy conflicts' on the other. Leaving the
state and foreign policy for later in the chapter, and concentrating
solely on the companies involved, our question is twofold. First,
supposing that these firms acted in unison, how would their quest for
differential accumulation relate to militarisation and conflict in the
region? And, second, is this hypothetical relationship consistent with the
facts?
Although the broader regime of tension and crisis was generally
beneficial for the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition, there were
nevertheless certain differences between the interests of its armament and
oil members. For the former, arms exports constituted a net addition to
sales, so their gain from Middle Eastern militarisation and armed conflict
was practically open ended. For the latter, however, the consequences of
tension and hostilities were beneficial only up to a point, for two
reasons. First, excessively high oil prices tended to encourage energy
substitution, weaken profits in downstream operations, and lure entry from
potential competitors. And, second, regional instability, if spun out of
control, could undermine the close cooperation between the companies and
oil-producing countries.
Hypothetically, then, we should expect the armament companies to
have had little objection to ever-growing militarisation and conflict -
this in contrast to the more qualified stance of the oil companies.
Specifically, we speculate that as long as the Petro-Core companies
managed to beat the 'big economy' average - that is, as long as they
accumulated differentially relative to dominant capital as a whole - they
judged their performance as satisfactory, and were generally content with
having 'tension but not
war'. However, when their rate of profit fell below that
average, their position turned hawkish, seeking open hostilities in order
to push up prices and boost their sagging performance. When that happened,
the more aggressive stance of the large oil companies brought them into a
temporary consensus with the leading armament firms. And it was at this
point, we argue, when the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition became
united, that a Middle East 'energy conflict' was prone to erupt.
Figure 5.7 Return on Equity: The
Petro-Core vs. the Fortune 500
SOURCE: Fortune; Standard & Poor's Compustat.
To see how well this hypothesis sits with the facts, consider
Figures 5.7 and 5.8. The first of these charts contrasts the
rate of return for the Petro-Core with the comparable rate for dominant
capital as a whole, approximated here by the Fortune 500 group of
companies. The second chart plots the difference between the two rates,
expressed in percentage points. In both diagrams, dark areas denote a
'danger zone': a period of negative differential accumulation for the
Petro-Core, and a consequent risk of a new 'energy conflict'. The eruption
of each such conflict is indicated in Figure 5.8 with a little
explosion sign.
The evidence arising from these charts is rather remarkable. First,
until the early 1990s, every single one of these 'danger zones' was
followed by the outbreak of an 'energy conflict' - the 1967 Arab-Israeli
War, the 1973 Arab-Israeli War, the 1979 Islamic Revolution in Iran and
the outbreak of the 1980-88 Iran-Iraq War and, recently, the 1990/91 Gulf
War. Second, the onset of each of these crises was followed by a
reversal of fortune, with the Petro-Core's rate of return rising above the
comparable big-economy average. And finally, none of these 'energy
conflicts' erupted without the Petro-Core first falling into the 'danger
zone'. (The figures also make clear that the mechanism was by no means
eternal. Indeed, after the 1990/91 Gulf War, a new 'danger zone' opened up
- and yet this time there was no 'energy conflict' to close it. Even the
2001 war in Afghanistan has done little to prop up prices. The reasons for
this change are dealt with at the end of the chapter.)
Given the complexity of Middle Eastern affairs, these three
regularities seem almost too systematic to be true. Indeed, is it possible
that the differential rate of return of six oil companies was all that we
needed in order to predict such major upheavals as the June 1967 War, the
Iran-Iraq conflict, or the Iraqi invasion to Kuwait? And what should we
make of the notion that Middle East conflicts were the main factor
'regulating' the differential accumulation of the Petro-Core? Finally, are
lower-than-normal earnings for the oil majors indeed a necessary condition
for Middle East energy wars? Maybe the process pictured in Figures
5.7 and 5.8 is a statistical mirage? Perhaps the real causes of
energy conflicts are totally different, only that by historical fluke they
happened to coincide with differential profitability?
Figure 5.8 Petro-Core's
Differential Accumulation and Middle East 'Energy Conflicts'
SOURCE: Fortune; Standard & Poor's Compustat.
For instance, one simple alternative, still in the realm of
business explanations, is that energy conflicts were triggered by
movements in profitability rather than differential profitability.
This, however, does not seem to be the case here. The figures show that
the rate of profit of the Petro-Core fell in 1969-70, 1972, 1975, 1977-78,
1980-82, 1985-87 and 1991. Energy conflicts, on the other hand, erupted
only in 1967 (after the Core's profits were rising), in 1973 and 1979-80
(after they were falling) and in 1990 (after they were rising).
Furthermore, despite falling profitability, no new energy conflict broke
out in 1969-70, 1976, 1983 or 1988. Clearly, then, there is no
straightforward connection between movements in the simple rate of profit
for the Petro-Core and the occurrence of conflicts.
Another possible explanation is that energy conflicts were
triggered not by setbacks for the Petro-Core, but by declining exports for
the oil-producing countries. According to this argument, the destabilising
impact of lower oil revenues would make governments more willing to engage
in conflict in order to raise them up. The facts, however, don't seem to
support this explanation either. For instance, Egyptian oil exports rose
from $35 million in 1970, to $47 million in 1972, and to $93 million in
1973 (United Nations Annual). If wars were indeed contingent on falling
state revenues, this should have worked against the Arab-Israeli
conflict in 1973. Similarly with the Iran-Iraq War. The conflict erupted
in 1980, after oil revenues for the two countries were climbing
rapidly, reaching $18.4 billion for Iran and an all time high of $26.9
for Iraq; and it ended in 1988, after revenues fell sharply to
$12.7 billion for Iran and to $15.9 for Iraq, exactly the opposite of what
we would expect based on the export logic (U.S. Department of Energy
Annual). Finally, the 1990 Iraqi invasion of Kuwait occurred after several
years of stable oil revenues, with Iraqi revenues during 1987-90
hovering around $15 billion annually (ibid.). Of course, prior to his
invasion to Kuwait, Saddam Hussain was under a growing financial strain
accumulated during his years of fighting against Iran, so he needed much
more than stable oil earnings to resolve his problems.
Nevertheless, as we shall argue below, this rationale was hardly
sufficient to outweigh a clear threat of forceful U.S. intervention - had
there been one. Now, of course, every one of these conflicts could be
explained by its own particular circumstances, many of which are related
neither to oil nor arms. But recall that our purpose is to see if there
was perhaps a broader logic to tie these conflicts together, and from this
viewpoint, regional and local factors alone, although crucial, do not
provide a picture nearly as consistent as the one offered by the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition.
The corporate members of this Coalition, we argue, were not 'free
riders' on the roller coaster of Middle East conflicts. Indeed, the
evidence indicates not only that these companies eventually gained
from militarisation and oil crises, but more fundamentally, that adverse
drops in their differential profits have been a most effective
leading indicator for upcoming 'energy conflicts'. This evidence
cannot easily be dismissed as a chance occurrence. By the standards of
empirical research, the links between differential accumulation on the one
hand, and militarisation, 'energy conflicts' and oil crises on the other,
are far too systematic and encompassing to be ignored. Clearly, there is
need here for further exploration. How, for instance, was the weapon trade
commercialised? What politicised the oil business? What role did the
superpowers play in the process? How did Middle East governments,
including Israel's, fit into the bigger picture? Did the large
corporations shape 'foreign policy' in the region, or were they themselves
instruments of such policy? Can we actually draw a line between state and
capital here? Should we? Let's turn then to look more closely at the
actual history of the process.
The 1967
Arab-Israeli War
Analyses of the June 1967 War are usually cast in terms of three
regional processes, none of which is directly related to oil. The first
process is of course the ethnic and cultural antagonism between Arabs and
Jews, which began at the turn of the century, and which developed after
1948 into a nationalist clash between Israel on the one hand, and the
Palestinians and the Arab states on the other (Safran 1978). The second
process concerns the barriers on rapidly growing population imposed by an
acute shortage of water. According to many writers this is the root cause
of the conflict between Israel and its immediate neighbours, Jordan, Syria
and Lebanon (Kelly 1986; Naff and Matson 1984; Rabinovitch 1983; and
Sexton 1990). The third process, which received considerable attention in
recent years, is the development since the 1950s of nuclear weapons by
Israel (Hersh 1991). Some, such as Aronson (1992; 1994-95), see this
development as crucial in determining Israel's foreign and security
policies, and as a major force steering the region's recent history.
Making
America 'Aware of the Issue'
Yet, the conflict was also related, even at that early stage, to
the broader, global significance of the Middle East. The
'free-flow' era after the Second World War was marked by U.S. concerns
regarding access to the region's oil fields. During the late 1940s and
early 1950s, many at the State Department saw Israel as a destabilising
factor. Military support to that country, argued the CIA, could provoke
anti-American sentiments, weaken the U.S. position in Iran, Turkey and
Greece, and possibly lead to a loss of control over the oil routes (Gazit,
1983a: 14). The Israelis, although formally non-aligned, were displeased
with these negative attitudes, particularly since they had so much to
offer. The sentiment of the country's elite in this matter was echoed by
Gershom Schocken, editor of the daily Ha'aretz:
"Israel had
proven its military might in the War of Independence, so making it
somewhat stronger could help the West keep the political balance in the
Middle East. According to this view, Israel would act as a watchdog. It
wouldn't become aggressive against the explicit wishes of America and
Britain. But, if, for whatever reason, the latter were to turn a blind
eye, Israel could be counted on to punish those neighbours whose attitude
towards the West had become a little too disrespectful..."
(Ha'aretz, 30 September 1951, cited in Orr and Machover 1961: 158)
Until the mid-1950s, however, Britain still seemed to be doing a
good job protecting the oil routes, and with its various positions in
Iraq, the oil emirates, and the Suez Canal looking secure, the Israeli
overtures were politely ignored. Ben-Gurion, though, was persistent. 'It's about time to make the
defence of Israel part and parcel of defending the free world', he
wrote to U.S. Secretary of State John Foster-Dulles (cited in Bar Zohar
1975: 1320). To demonstrate his commitment, he offered in 1951 to secretly
dispatch an Israeli battalion in order to assist the U.S. war effort in
Korea, while on another occasion he proposed that Washington finance a
250,000-strong Israeli military force, dedicated to defending the region
against Soviet intrusions (Gazit 1983a: 16-19). 'There was something pathetic
and shameful', wrote his biographer, 'in these repeated attempts to hold on to the U.S.
skirt, particularly when the latter was trying, again and again, to get
rid of the embarrassing nuisance...' (Bar Zohar 1975: 1320). And
yet the efforts continued. Pinchas Lavon, who replaced Ben-Gurion as
Defence Minister in 1953, tried a new, bolder direction. His intention was
to set up a terrorist network in the Arab countries, with the purpose of
attacking U.S. embassies and cultural centres. This, he hoped, would
alienate the Americans against their Arab hosts, helping them realise that
their only true ally in the region was Israel (Sharet 1978: Vols. II-III).
The hasty plot was uncovered, and although the affair was never thoroughly
investigated, Lavon had to resign, and eventually so did Ben-Gurion. The
Israeli military, though, continued the escalation, using massive
'retaliations' against Palestinian guerrillas in the hope of warming up
the conflict and pulling the United States into the fold (Sharet 1978:
Vol. III; Cafcafi 1994: 73).
The crowning achievement of this strategy was Israel's 1956
invasion of the Sinai peninsula, followed by Britain and France's attempt
to take over the Suez Canal. U.S. News and World Report was quick
to summarise the obvious: 'Why did Britain and France go to war against Egypt? In order to
topple Nasser, to control the Suez Canal and save their oil' (9
November 1956, cited in Orr and Machover 1961: 297). The Israeli elite, on
the other hand, denied any conspiracy. According to the official version,
Ben-Gurion never went to France on the eve of the war to sign the Sèvres
Treaty between the conspirators; there was no prior plan for France and
Britain to take over the Canal in order to 'separate' the warring
factions; and there was no intention to topple Nasser. The whole thing was
an act of self-defence, pure and simple. Israel was threatened with
annihilation, and so took a pre-emptive strike. Thirty years later,
though, Shimon Peres, who participated in orchestrating the operation,
presented a rather different version:
"If it were not
for the Suez Operation, the danger was that Britain and France would leave
the Middle East before the Americans became aware of the issue, therefore
allowing the Russians to penetrate and shape the region without the U.S.A.
Following the Suez Operation, the Americans became committed to a regional
balance. It was this commitment which shaped the U.S. stance toward the
Six Day War..." (cited in Evron 1986: 164)
In other words, Ben-Gurion and his clique managed to trick their
allies as well as foes. Not only was there no threat of 'annihilation',
but the 'eternal
Franco- Israeli friendship', which Peres always took credit for
cementing, was itself merely a temporary move. The real goal was to make
the Americans 'aware of
the issue'.
Subcontracting
And aware they became. Following the Suez debacle, the 'free flow'
of oil no longer looked secure. The emergence of Pan-Arabism and
increasing Soviet intrusion into the region presented a growing threat to
the feudal regimes of Saudi Arabia and surrounding sheikdoms. In 1958,
Faisal, the pro-American king of Iraq was assassinated, and the 1954
Baghdad Pact erected by the British fell apart. In that same year, Syria
and Egypt merged into the United Arab Republic, prompting King Hussein of
Jordan to request American aid and British paratroops for his protection,
and the Maronite government in Beirut to invite the U.S. marines. These
developments gave rise to the new 'Eisenhower Doctrine'. According to this
doctrine, the United States itself would assume military responsibility
for the Persian Gulf and the Arab Peninsula (Gold 1993: 35). However, the
new realignment also required to fortify the perimeter surrounding the oil
region, and here Israel came in handy. Valued for its stability,
pro-Western characteristics and logistical potential, it was declared a
'strategic asset' for the West (Safran 1978: Ch. 20). With persistence and
a dose of good luck, the dream had finally come true.
Initially, the State Department was careful to not openly support
the Jewish state. The CIA, however, having fewer inhibitions, quickly
started fashioning covert liaisons with local politicians and security
officials. Many of these relations were built around a proposal by
Ben-Gurion that Israel create a peripheral, pro-American alliance with
non-Arab countries, such as Turkey, Iran and Ethiopia, in order to contain
Arab radicalism. A central feature of this 'peripheral alliance' was a
secret agreement, code-named KK Mountain. According to the
agreement, the Israeli Mossad would become a permanent paid
'subcontractor' for the CIA, carrying out delicate operations which the
U.S. legislator and judiciary would otherwise find difficult to stomach.
Since the region's 'bastion of democracy' was much more lenient in these
matters, the deal seemed only fair, and theMossad quickly found itself
involved in numerous proxy undertakings around the world. In the Middle
East and Africa, these included military assistance to various groups and
regimes, such as the royal forces in Ethiopia and Yemen, the Kurds in
Iraq, the army and secret service of the Iranian Shah, the secret police
in Morocco, the security forces and military of South Africa, and the
rulers of Uganda, Zaire and Nigeria. Later, the Israelis would also
diversify into Latin America, providing their ware and knowledge to
pro-American dictatorships such as Panama, Chile, Nicaragua, Honduras, El
Salvador and Guatemala (Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: Chs 5, 9, 10).
Some of these operations were allegedly part of the CIA's effort to
have the new Kennedy Administration pay more attention to the Middle East.
The role of the CIA is especially noteworthy, because, after the Second
World War, and particularly since the early 1950s, the Agency's Middle
Eastern activities were almost exclusively handled by the ARAMCO partners
and Bechtel (McCartney 1989: Ch. 10). Kennedy wasn't swayed. Despite his
favourable attitude toward the petroleumindustry and the close oil
connections of some his top officials, [10
footnote] he continued pursuing his policy of appeasement toward
Nasser. However, his 'New Look' doctrine also permitted, for the first
time, American military shipments to Israel. Contrary to the
'nuclear-containment' policy of his predecessors, Kennedy emphasised the
use of conventional weapons and direct involvement against Soviet
subversion. In 1960, he announced that he was not opposed to a 'military
balance' between Israel and the Arab countries, and that in global matters
the United States had 'special relations' with Israel, comparable only to
its relations with Britain (Safran 1978: 581; and Gazit 1983a: 33).
Breaking
Nasser's Bones Asunder
Initially, the change may have been partly motivated by Kennedy's
desire to check Israel's nuclear development programme, and to prevent an
out-of-control nuclear arms race between Israel and Egypt (Gazit 1983b:
49-56). Another possibility is that Kennedy was simply paying off the
Jewish Lobby for financing his election campaign (Hersh 1991: Ch. 8). But
toward the mid- 1960s, when attempts to appease Nasser seemed to go
nowhere, his successor, President Johnson, put Kennedy's 'special
relations' into practice, and began sending Israel large military
shipments. Despite his preoccupation with the intensifying conflict in
Vietnam, Johnson was nevertheless worried about the fighting in Yemen,
where Egyptian troops had on a number of occasions crossed the border into
Saudi Arabia. After the end of its involvement in Libya and in the Congo,
the United States ceased its economic support to Egypt altogether, and
instead switched to overtly assisting the Jewish state. In 1966, at the
height of its entanglement in Vietnam, Washington began giving Israel, for
the first time, heavy assault weapons, including tanks, aircraft
and missiles.
In that year, Soviet involvement in the region seemed more menacing
than ever. First, Britain announced it would soon be leaving Aden,
notwithstanding the ongoing Soviet-backed war in neighbouring Yemen, just
south of the world's richest oil fields; then, the pro-Soviet Ba'ath party
staged a coup in Syria; and finally, the Kremlin began to promote a
socialist union between Egypt, Syria, Algeria and Iraq, threatening to
engulf Saudi Arabia from the west and north. Given its difficulties in
Vietnam, the United States was not prepared to counteract these
developments directly, but Israel certainly was and did.
Toward the end of 1966, the Arab-Israeli dispute was again heating
up. In November, Israel staged a massive raid into the Jordanian town of
Samoa, officially in retaliation for guerrilla attacks. Then, in April
1967, an Israeli tractor, sent to cultivate a demilitarised zone just
beneath the Golan Heights, sparked a border skirmish which ended with
humiliating Syrian losses. Adding insult to injury, the Israelis went on
to announce their intentions of forcibly dethroning the Damascus regime.
Faced with mounting challenges to his Pan-Arab leadership, Nasser was more
or less compelled to respond, moving two army divisions into the Sinai
desert and closing the Straits of Tiran. There are, of course, other
explanations. Aronson (1994-95), for instance, argues that the escalation
was in fact an unintended consequence of Nasser trying to stop the
development of nuclear weapons by Israel. One way or the other, it is
clear that the Americans (like the French and British before them) hoped
that Israel would use the opportunity to topple Nasser, and the closing of
the Tiran Straits now offered the pretext for a pre-emptive strike.
Contrary to popular belief, the Israeli and American leaderships
had little doubt about the outcome of the looming war. The certainty of
Arab defeat was also known to Nasser - as well as to the other Arab
participants - but given their internal disputes, they found it
politically impossible to ignore Israeli provocations, and were thus
increasingly drawn toward a point of no return. [11
footnote] Following the closure of the Straits of Tiran, Israel
scheduled its attack for 25 May, but had to wait until 6 June, after Meir
Amit, head of the Israeli Mossad, returned from an emergency trip to
Washington with the 'green light' to 'break Nasser's bones asunder' (Haber 1987: 214-16). And so,
by maintaining its loyalty to U.S. strategic interests in the region,
Israel had finally succeeded in joining the U.S. orbit as an official
satellite, a process which would further intensify during the 1970s and
1980s.
Preoccupied with the 'free flow' of oil, the Petro-Core may have
viewed the war's outcome as highly favourable: Soviet aspirations were
undermined and the cause of Pan-Arabism suffered a serious blow. However,
the companies must have also noticed the positive effect the war had on
their differential profitability (see Figures 5.7 and 5.8) -
an ominous sign that their 'free-flow' system was itself coming to an end.
[12
footnote] And as if to hasten the process, the aftermath of the war
was marked by increasing arms exports. Rewarded for its victory, Israel
began receiving F-4 Phantom aircraft made by McDonnell Douglas, which were
previously sold only to Britain and Germany. With this, the door was now
open for an arms race of sophisticated weapons, a race which would
eventually help 'limit' the flow of oil and introduce the petroleum
business into the new era of 'crisis'.
The 1973
Arab-Israeli War
The 1968 U.S. presidential elections brought in an administration
highly attuned to the coinciding interests of oil and arms. Nixon's
campaigns were supported heavily, and sometimes illegally, by
contributions from both defence contractors and oil companies, while his
Secretary of State Kissinger enjoyed close connections with the
Rockefellers, and proposed an aggressive realpolitik which on more than
one occasion entertained the feasibility of 'limited' nuclear war. [13
footnote] In the eyes of this new administration, the 1967 War did
little to secure U.S. interests in the Middle East. Qaddafi's 1969
showdown with the oil companies in Libya and the attempted coup in Saudi
Arabia were disconcerting reminders of pending regional hazards.
Washington, so it seemed, must pay more attention, not less, to this
troubled area.
The Realist
View
And yet, that was easier said than done. In 1969, the United States
began withdrawing its troops from Vietnam, and with warmer relations with
China and the declaration of Détente, the new 'Nixon Doctrine' called for
a lower defence budget. Instead of Kennedy's strategy to prepare for '2½ wars', Nixon and
Kissinger offered resources for only '1½ wars'. In 1969, the policy kicked in, and
domestic military spending started to fall. From a statist viewpoint, the
result was to weaken U.S. capabilities in the Middle East, this precisely
when the region emerged as one of the world's most sensitive (Gold 1993:
40).
Moreover, Britain's withdrawal from its last stronghold in the
Persian Gulf, together with the United States losing its last strategic
air base in Libya, created a military vacuum. The solution, stipulated by
Kissinger, was for the United States to concentrate only on 'core
conflicts', leaving 'peripheral conflicts' to be handled by local
pro-American forces. The consequences for the region were twofold. First,
Washington embarked on massive arms exports, initially to Israel and the
'twin pillars', Iran and Saudi Arabia, but later also to Egypt and other
countries. Second, State Department attempts at settling the Arab-Israeli
conflict were now frustrated by White House support for Israel (Safran
1978: Ch. 23). With Middle Eastern affairs increasingly handled by the
Nixon-Kissinger duo rather than State Secretary Rogers, Israel was now
used as a threat against anti- American Arab countries (Kissinger 1979:
1285, 1289). Kissinger was particularly intimidated by what he regarded as
deliberate Soviet challenges, and in 1970 worked out, together with
Yitzhak Rabin, then Israel's ambassador to Washington, a joint plan for
military intervention in case Syria or Iraq attacked King Hussein of
Jordan.
These observations do not sit well with the realist perspective.
First, given the split between the conciliatory position of the State
Department and the aggressive stance of the President, it is not clear
what 'national interest' American policy makers were trying to achieve.
Second, the type of cannon diplomacy entertained by Kissinger did not look
particularly conducive to his goal of regional stability. Indeed,
according to Safran (1978: Ch. 23), the United States continued to send
arms to the region, this despite its own fears that an Israeli victory
against Arab aggression would cause chaos and seriously disturb the flow
of oil.
The
Coalition's View
From the viewpoint of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition,
however, U.S. foreign policy here seems pretty consistent. Declining
military spending at home hurt the large defence contractors badly
(Sampson 1977: 214-21), and with pressures from these contractors
coinciding with his own strategic outlook, Nixon moved to further
commercialise arms exports. His new doctrine stipulated that the burden of
defending U.S. allies - financially as well as in manpower - should now be
borne by those allies themselves (Ferrari et al. 1987: 21). In order to do
that, explained military contractor David Packard (then acting as Deputy
Secretary of Defense), the United States was ready to 'give or sell [to these
allies] the tools they need for this bigger load we are urging them to
assume' (quoted in Sampson 1977: 243). In the Middle East, the
Nixon Doctrine elevated the arms race to a new level. Commercialisation,
to be sure, was not strictly enforced. Israel, for instance, was unable to
pay for its rapidly rising military imports; and, yet, to its great
surprise, Washington was willing to give them for free (Rabin 1979: Ch.
4). [14
footnote] Officials in Jerusalem celebrated this as a 'huge
achievement' (Gazit, 1983a: 53), only that they failed to notice the even
greater achievement of other states, who, unlike Israel, were both able
and willing to pay.
The most 'successful' of the lot was Iran. On their visit to Tehran
in 1972, Nixon and Kissinger reputedly agreed to sell Iran 'virtually any conventional
arms it wanted' (cited in Sampson 1977: 252). And with this newly
acquired freedom to sell, U.S. armament companies quickly started courting
the country's Shah, whom Washington now appointed as 'policeman of the
Gulf'. At the time, domestic sales to the Pentagon were hitting
rock bottom, so military exports to Iran provided a much needed lifeline
for many contractors (Figure 5.3). The extent of these exports, however,
depended crucially on the petroleum revenues of the Peacock Throne, an
important detail which both Nixon and Kissinger were most surely aware of.
[15
footnote] And, indeed, the oil industry, too, was undergoing a
profound transformation. With weakening prices and falling profitability,
as illustrated in Figures 5.5 and 5.7, the large petroleum
companies came to realise the potential benefit of a stronger OPEC. The
cartel's apparent resolve to control output impressed the oil majors, and
their London Oil Policy Group was now ready to accept a new
revenue-sharing agreement (Odell 1979: 105, 215). But although the price
of oil started to rise in 1971, the Petro-Core's rate of profit continued
to linger and, in 1972, fell dangerously below the Fortune 500 'normal'
(Figures 5.7 and 5.8).
And then came the October 1973 'energy conflict'. The war brought a
sharp increase in prices, restoring the oil companies' differential
profitability high above the big-economy's average. At the same time, it
also generated dramatic increases in the oil revenues of Arab countries,
with immediate consequences for the arms trade. In 1974, a year after the
war, the Middle East surpassed South East Asia to become the world's
largest market for imported weapons, with over one-third of the global
trade.
While there is no evidence to implicate the U.S. Administration as
instigator in the conflict, there is also little to indicate it keenly
tried to prevent it. To be sure, the war didn't catch the Nixon government
by surprise. Warned by King Faisal of Saudi Arabia already in the
beginning of 1973, the ARAMCO partners were aware of what was coming, and
they passed on the information to Washington (Blair 1976: 266-8; Sampson
1975: 243-8; and Yergin 1991: 593-7). A similar message came from a CIA
study (incidentally co-authored by the same analyst who anticipated that
the 1967 War would last only six days), which concluded that the Egyptians
were planning to attack Israel (Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: 171). Indeed,
Kissinger was directly informed of the pending assault, both by Jordan's
King Hussein (who between 1957 and 1977 was a paid CIA agent), and by
sources close to President Sadat of Egypt (Neff 1988: 105).
The U.S.
'National Interest': What Price Stability?
These observations seem perplexing. If Nixon and Kissinger were
indeed concerned with maintaining regional stability as stipulated in the
realist literature, why didn't they heed Saudi requests that Washington
softened its support for Israel? To suggest that this was because the
Administration was by then irrevocably committed to the Israeli cause is
not persuasive; for if that was the case, why did it fail to warn the
Israelis of the pending calamity? Indeed, why did Kissinger caution Israel
not to fire the first shot when the latter finally realised that Egypt and
Syria were about to attack? One common interpretation is that Kissinger
wanted the Arabs to win their self-respect and some territory, which would
then be traded for peace through his own mediation (Hersh 1991: 227).
However, from a statist viewpoint, Kissinger was walking on a tightrope
here. The problem, according to his own admission, was how to achieve a
'balanced' outcome - one in which the war would end after Israel had
recovered some of its earlier losses, but before it had the chance to
destroy its opponents. For Kissinger, this must have been a real problem.
He had absolute confidence in Israel's military ability and feared that an
Israeli victory would be devastating for U.S. regional interests (possibly
by inciting leftist coups and encouraging Soviet intervention). Yet
despite the obvious danger, he stuck to his plan, moving to broker a
ceasefire only at the last moment, after Israel had threatened to use
nuclear weapons (Safran 1978: Ch. 23).
Clearly, then, realist calculations alone do not tell the whole
story. Attuned to the plight of the oil and armament companies, Kissinger
must have also pondered how an oil crisis might boost their coinciding
interests. And indeed, after the war, with petrodollars and weapondollars
locked in an upward spiral, peace between Israel and the Arabs was put on
the backburner. The more urgent task now was to keep the 'balance of
power'; and sure enough, instead of preaching reconciliation, we find the
U.S. ambassador to Cairo recommending military shipments to Egypt, while
his colleagues in Kuwait and Saudi Arabia explain the merit of
American-made aircraft to local rulers (New York Times, 21 July 1975,
cited in Frenkel 1991: 76). Working now for the new Ford Administration
but still pursuing his original plan, Kissinger helped establish an
'interim agreement' between the warring factions. This time, though, the
United States held the carrot as well as the stick; it could use Israel as
a threat against pro-Soviet Arab regimes, but it could also force it to
return occupied Arab land to those who promised to leave the Soviet orbit
and cross the floor onto the American side (Safran 1978: Ch. 25). However,
the U.S. Administration was also careful to insist that any interim
agreement should not evolve into a comprehensive settlement. When in July
of 1975 the Israeli government appeared willing to go to a peace
conference in Geneva, President Ford threatened to withdraw American
assistance (New York Times, 3 July 1975). The imperative of
maintaining tension was spelled out clearly less than a year later.
Appearing before the Jewish-American Congress in April of 1976, Henry
Kissinger effectively asserted that a comprehensive Middle East peace
depended not so much on the warring factions, but rather on the
superpowers first agreeing on their respective spheres of influence
(reported in Meyer 1976: 157).
These pursuits on the armament front also help shed some light on
the Administration's energy policy. On the surface, Washington's view on
the subject seemed confused, even contradictory. Based on his analysis of
over one thousand State Department cables and papers obtained under the
Freedom of Information Act, Yergin (1991: 84) concluded that, between 1974
and 1981, the U.S. government in fact objected to higher oil prices. But
then he simultaneously inferred that the government didn't want to see
those prices lowered either (p. 643). This indecisiveness, Yergin argued,
was rooted in a conflicting quest for lower energy cost at home, coupled
with a richer and thus more stable Middle East. And yet, if the goal was
indeed stability, why send so much armament to the region, particularly
when Washington itself doubted their contribution to peace? And what about
the support of Kissinger and the International Energy Agency for a 'minimum safeguard
price' as a means of protecting Western interests? (Sampson
1975: 306; and Turner 1983: 184). Perhaps the Administration, despite its
declarations to the contrary, was in fact interested in neither lower
oil prices nor regional stability? After all, representatives of the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition were now increasingly involved in
'state policy', so couldn't they have pushed things in that direction?
The realist failure to square the circle around oil prices is only
understandable. The basic reason is that, by the 1970s, while the world
was already well into the 'limited flow' era, realist theories were still
stuck in the 'free flow' logic. Stephen Krasner, for example, claimed that
there was a negative trade-off between the level and variability of
petroleum prices (1978b: 39-40). The consequence, he concluded, was that
policy makers had to choose between low but variable prices, or stable but
high ones. Yet, when those lines were written, this menu had already
become irrelevant, and in fact misleading. From the late 1960s onward,
with oil shifting to a 'limited flow' footing, the relationship between
the level and variability of prices became positive. The choice now
was not between low and variable oil prices as opposed to high and stable
ones, but rather between low and stable prices against high and volatile
ones. Obviously, this transition fundamentally altered the relationship
between the oil companies and the so-called 'national interest'. During
the early period, when the companies were concerned mainly with
concessions, the Administration's willingness to have higher prices in
order to secure stability and access seemed sensible. It helped the
companies, as well as the broader U.S. 'national interest'. Since the late
1960s, however, harmony gave way to discord. The United States could no
longer pay higher prices in order to achieve access and price stability;
it couldn't, simply because access was no longer negotiable, whereas
higher prices were clearly causing greater instability. The oil
companies, on the other hand, were now interested not in access but in
higher prices. Contrary to the earlier situation, therefore, there was now
clear conflict between the companies and the 'national interest', and the
Administration's pursuit of both instability and higher prices only
indicates where its allegiances lay.
Initially, the coinciding interests of the Arma-Core and Petro-Core
in regional turmoil were blurred by the imaginative use of language, which
insisted on equating arms shipments with 'stabilisation'. For example,
Secretary of State Rogers, who would later become a retainer for the
Iranian Shah and board member of the oil company Sohio, characterised U.S.
military sales as having a 'stabilising influence' - this in contrast to the 'invitation for
trouble' posed by similar Soviet shipments (Engler 1977: 242).
Similarly, Kissinger (1981: 182), using a more academic lingo, explained
that the 'balance of
power is a kind of policeman, whose responsibility is to prevent peaceful
countries from feeling impotent and aggressors from becoming
reckless'. Eventually, however, as the Orwellian identity of
weapons and peace began to dissipate, the true forces at play came into
focus.
The rising influence of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition
coincided with the new policies of Jimmy Carter. Unlike Nixon's, the
'Carter Doctrine' moved from emphasising loyal proxies - chiefly Israel
and the 'twin pillars', Iran and Saudi Arabia - to direct military
intervention. With growing nervousness on the part of the Saudi pillar -
first in response to Soviet involvement in the Horn of Africa, and later
as a consequence of Soviet participation in the Yemen conflict - Carter
and his national security adviser, Zbigniew Brzezinski, decided to build a
'Rapid Deployment Joint Task Force', or RDJTF (Long 1985: 62). As they saw
it, the lesson from Iran was that the United States should not count on
local proxies, and must use its own forces to protect its own interests
(Quandt 1979: 543). This fitted well with the broader strategic rethinking
in Washington. According to Brzezinski (1983: 454), events and decisions
in 1979-80 had fundamentally altered the U.S. global strategic position.
The Middle East - which was previously seen as semi-neutral and protected
from Soviet power by a defence belt comprising Turkey, Iran, Pakistan and
Afghanistan - no longer seemed invincible. As a consequence, U.S. dual
commitments in Europe and the Far East were supplemented by a third
strategic commitment toward what was now known as 'West Asia'. The
resources needed to support this new pledge, however, were unavailable,
and so in order to bypass congressional objection, part of the military
deployment was financed by Saudi petrodollars (Gold 1993: 51).
Thus, notwithstanding his desire to promote world peace, President
Carter was subject to considerable pressures to act otherwise. At home,
his was the first administration to raise domestic military spending after
almost a decade of decline (Figure 5.3). On the international
arena, Carter indeed announced a policy of restraints on arms exports,
which, in its first 15 months, led to the cancellation of 614 requests
from 92 countries, worth over $1 billion (Ferrari et al. 1987: 25). Yet,
despite these limitations, and contrary to the new statist stand on the
principle of American 'self-defence', total U.S. arms exports continued to
increase (albeit still slowly), particularly to the Middle East. Somewhat
paradoxically, Carter, who was often perceived as a peacemaker and
promoter of regional reconciliation, was also the president who
contributed the most toward opening the Arab market to U.S. weaponry. In
1978, toward the Camp David Accord, he initiated the first 'combination
deal', whereby U.S. armament producers simultaneously equipped
several warring factions - a pattern which was then promptly
institutionalised by other arms-exporting countries as a means of
promoting peace through arms sales. [16
footnote]
The 1979 Iranian
Revolution and the 1980-88 Iran-Iraq War
The Hostage
Crisis
Yet the ongoing rearmament during the mid-1970s was merely
sufficient to keep oil prices from falling, and in the absence of a
serious upheaval, the Petro-Core's profitability in 1977 and 1978 again
dropped into the 'danger zone', below the big-economy's average
(Figures 5.7 and 5.8). Fortunately for the Coalition,
though, help was on the way, with turmoil again starting to build up. The
Islamic Revolution which began in 1978 failed to have a significant effect
on the oil market, although the potential was clearly there. In this
light, the involvement of the U.S. Administration in the onset of the 1979
oil crisis is noteworthy. Despite the delicate situation in Iran,
President Carter quickly granted asylum to the ousted Shah, thus
triggering the hostage crisis. When Iran threatened to withdraw its U.S.
banking deposits, the President immediately retaliated by seizing Iranian
assets.
The background leading to the seizure was outlined by journalist
Anthony Sampson (1981: Ch. 17; Ha'aretz, 2 January 1981). During
the period from 1976 to 1978, Iran borrowed $3.8 billion to finance arms
purchases. On the eve of the Iranian Revolution, an outstanding debt of
$500 million was owed to a consortium headed by Chase Manhattan, which
also held $433 million in Iranian deposits. In theory, these deposits
could have been withheld as a forced collateral, only that Chase had no
legal right to do so - that is, unless instructed by the U.S. government
for reasons of 'national security'. And as it turns out, this is precisely
what happened - although not without help from David Rockefeller, the
bank's chairman and one of its principal owners. Sampson reveals how Henry
Kissinger, acting as a special adviser to Chase Manhattan at the time, and
Jack McCloy, a former chairman of the bank, courted President Carter, who
was himself closely associated with the Rockefellers through the
Trilateral Commission, so that he granted asylum to the Shah despite the
fragile political atmosphere. Kissinger later told Sampson that there was
nothing subversive in these activities, arguing it was inconceivable that
'a few private
citizens' could affect state policy. The Islamic government, in any
event, was deeply offended. Turmoil ensued, and as the script unfolded,
Tehran threatened to withdraw its U.S. deposits, to which Carter
immediately retaliated by freezing them. The official justification was
that the freeze was necessary to defend the integrity of the American
banking system, although the real risk couldn't be that serious. Iran had
roughly $8 billion dollars worth of deposits, but of these only $1 billion
were 'call money' available on demand - less than 1% of the U.S. system's
outstanding cash balance. Moreover, most of these deposits were held in
London, so even if drawn out, the only place for them to go was back into
the Euro market. Clearly, the financial system as whole was not at threat.
Certain institutions, however, particularly Chase and Citibank of the
Rockefeller group, were vulnerable, and had much to gain by the freeze.
The 'Sting'
The hostage crisis in Iran sparked panic, and the price of oil
finally began to rise. Adding to the turmoil, the Soviet Union invaded
Afghanistan in late 1979, and in 1980 the Iraqis attacked Iran. Oil prices
were now climbing beyond $35 per barrel, pulling the Petro-Core's
profitability safely out of the 'danger zone'. And with Middle East oil
revenues on the rise, the flow of imported weapons was also growing
rapidly. To some extent, both the invasion of Afghanistan and Iraq's
assault on Iran were rooted in the rising threat of Islamic
fundamentalism. Yet the U.S. government, although happy to see this threat
being checked, was not entirely antagonistic to the Khomeini regime.
According to several sources analysed in Cockburn and Cockburn (1991:
317-18), during the last year of his administration, Carter embarked on a
'sting operation' which, if successful, would have both helped his
re-election and caused Iran to renew its demand for American weapons. The
underpinnings of his strategy were relatively straightforward. With much
of their sophisticated arsenal made in the United States, the Iranians
were crucially dependent on U.S. spare parts and ammunition. In this
context, a major conflict, preferably starting before the 1980 elections,
could convince Iran to release the embassy hostages in return for American
military re-supply. The unsuspecting carrier of that plan was Iraq's
Saddam Hussein. With blessing from Jordan and Kuwait, promises of Saudi
finances and, most importantly, a warm endorsement from Zbigniew
Brzezinski, whose declared aim was to see Iran 'punished from all sides',
Hussein swallowed the bait, and began advancing his forces into Iran
(Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: 392). Unfortunately for Carter, the timing of
the 'sting' was out of sync. Once Iraq launched its attack, his
administration condemned it and began soliciting the Iranians to trade
hostages for spare parts. But that was too late. Apparently, Iran already
had a secret agreement with the U.S. Republican Party, according to which
the hostages would be released only after the elections. And so although
the weapons were ready to flow, Carter was no longer there to benefit from
the deal. [17
footnote] For the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition, of course,
the deal was manna from heaven, regardless of who won the election -
although naturally, it much preferred having Reagan on its side than
Carter.
During Reagan's presidency, the Middle East was defined - in some
sense paradoxically - as being increasingly important for the U.S.
'national interest'. In 1983, Reagan created a new military central
command, or CENTCOM, to include the entire area of 'West Asia' from India
to the Horn of Africa. CENTCOM's mandate emphasised active defence over
deterrence. Its capabilities, however, were very limited. It wasn't able,
for example, to counter a Soviet challenge against the oil zone in
southern Iran, and certainly not to embark on a larger operation (Gold
1993: 69). Moreover, with funding being tight, the new focus on West Asia
had to come at the expense of American military commitments in Europe and
East Asia - this at a time when the significance to the U.S. of Middle
East oil, as well as of the Soviet danger, were in fact declining,
as we describe later in the chapter.
The Network
While the importance of oil and Soviet power were apparently waning
under Reagan, the political leverage of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar
Coalition was soaring to new highs. Vice-President George Bush - a former
Director of the CIA and an oil millionaire in his own right - had close
acquaintance with the petroleum industry, and strong ties to ultra
right-wing groups. As his first Secretary of State, the President
nominated Alexander Haig, previously a director of Chase Manhattan and
President and Chief Executive Officer of United Technology. [18
footnote] Reagan also nominated Donald Regan, a partner and
chairman of Merrill Lynch, as his Treasury Secretary. Merrill Lynch, much
like Chase Manhattan and United Technology, also had special links to the
Middle East. In 1978, the company acquired White Weld, an international
investment firm that advised the Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency (SAMA) on
how to manage its $100 billion portfolio and guided the investment of a
daily inflow of about 450 million petrodollars. As his Assistant Secretary
for International Affairs, Regan chose David Mulford, who until then was
running White Weld's operations in Saudi Arabia (Business Week, 22
July 1985). Other oil-related appointments included the nomination of Paul
Volker as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, who was then succeeded by
Alan Greenspan; the former was linked to the Rockefeller group, whereas
the latter, besides being a groupie of Ayn Rand, was a director at both
Mobil Oil and J.P. Morgan prior to his appointment.
However, the most important representatives of the Weapondollar-
Petrodollar Coalition who found their way into the Reagan Administration
were the veterans of Bechtel Corporation, the world's largest contractor
of military installations and energy-related projects. [19
footnote] Bechtel has had a long history of building political ties
at home and abroad (cf. McCartney 1989). Among other things, the company
was the driving force behind the election campaigns of Presidents Edgar
Hoover, Dwight Eisenhower and Ronald Reagan; it had close associates in
the CIA, including Agency Directors William Casey, Richard Helms and John
McCone; [20
footnote] it courted special relations with the Dulles brothers;
and it has dominated decision-making at the Atomic Energy Commission and
the Export-Import Bank. On the international scene, Bechtel acted
simultaneously as an arm of the CIA, as well as the unofficial
representative of foreign governments, particularly Saudi Arabia, in the
United States. These and numerous other connections, often supplemented by
substantial bribes and clandestine operations, helped win Bechtel some of
the world's largest construction projects. [21
footnote] But what made these projects so valuable to begin with
was the unfolding 'energy crisis' since the early 1970s.
Bechtel entered the Middle East after the Second World War as a
major contractor for the ARAMCO partners, but until the consolidation of
OPEC its activities in the region were relatively limited. It was only
with the oil price explosion of the early 1970s, that the contracts began
piling up. Among others, these included the construction of natural gas
projects in Algeria and Abu Dhabi, power stations in Cairo, and
refineries, airports and entire petrochemical cities in Saudi Arabia. In
addition, many of the company's other energy-related projects - such as
Quebec's hydroelectric James Bay complex, the Alaska oil pipeline,
Indonesia's liquefied natural gas facilities, and nuclear reactor plants
in the United States and elsewhere - were themselves partly the
consequence of rising oil prices. The company also became a major
constructor of military installations - mainly for U.S. forces, but also
for other sovereigns, particularly in cash-rich Arab countries.
By the early 1980s, Bechtel's international operations had risen to
over onehalf of its business, and the person who guided this transition
since the mid-1970s was the company's president, George Shultz. Toward the
1980 election, Shultz grew worried about candidate Ronald Reagan, whose
fixation on laissez faire and small government threatened Bechtel's
lifeline. However, after a series of re-educational meetings with Bechtel
executives and associates of the Rockefeller group, the presidential
hopeful came back to his senses, at least enough to make Shultz an avid
supporter. Once in office, Reagan began drawing on the talent of Bechtel
officials. As his initial Defense Secretary he chose Casper Weinberger,
who until then was a Bechtel vice-president, and in 1982, he asked Shultz
to replace Haig as Secretary of State. Other Bechtel veterans with key
positions in the new administration included, National Security Adviser
Richard Allen; Deputy Secretary of Energy Kenneth Davis; and Philip Habib,
whom Reagan sent as his Special Envoy to the Middle East while still on
Bechtel's payroll.
The convergence of oil and armament interests in the Reagan
Administration was paralleled to some extent in their own corporate
boardrooms, mainly through interlocking directorships which provide an
informal setting for exchanging ideas and coordinating collective action.
For example, during the 1980s, the chairman and chief executive officer of
Standard Oil of Indiana (Swearingen) was a director of both Chase
Manhattan and Lockheed; the board of directors of McDonnell Douglas
included a director of Phillips Petroleum (Chetkovich) and a director of
Shell Canada (McDonald); the chairman and president of United Technologies
(Gray) was a director of both Exxon and Citibank; Boeing shared one
director with Mobil and three with Chevron, including the latter's
chairman (Keller); and the Chevron board included a director from Allied
Signal (Hills), as well as the president and chief executive of Hewlett
Packard (Yound) (based on Moody's Annual; Adams 1982).
Nourishing
the Conflict
Whether the oil and armament companies indeed colluded to advance
their common interests remains an open question, but the policies of the
Reagan Administration certainly worked on their behalf. At home, Reagan
helped consolidate the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition by embarking on
the largest defence build-up in peacetime, while simultaneously reducing
corporate taxes. The obvious result was a rapidly rising budget deficit,
which horrified the economists but delighted the arms contractors and oil
companies. [22
footnote] And in the Middle East, the new Administration continued
the policies of its predecessors, though apparently with much greater
vigour. Whereas for Carter arms exports were an 'exceptional foreign policy
implement', Reagan took the view that they were 'an essential element of
[U.S.] global defense posture and an indispensable component of its
foreign policy', moving to eliminate many of their previously
imposed restrictions (U.S. Congress 1991: 20). Of course, in order to
enable buyers to pay for the outgoing weapons, Middle East 'energy
conflicts' had to be continuously nourished, a task to which the new
Administration turned with little delay.
Building on their earlier success, Washington and Tehran were now
trading regularly in exotic commodities. The United States secretly
supplied weapons to the Ayatollah Khomeini, for which the latter paid with
released hostages held by Iranian-backed forces in Lebanon, plus hard cash
which the Americans then used to finance the Contra rebels in Nicaragua.
The elaborate scheme, popularly known as the 'Iran-Contra Affair', was
conceived and approved at the highest echelons, including President
Reagan, Vice-President Bush, Secretary of State Shultz, Secretary of
Defense Weinberger, CIA Director William Casey, and National Security
Advisers Robert McFarlane and John Poindexter (New York Times, 19
January 1994). The purpose of the scheme, though, involved more than
hostages and rebels. Its other goal, less publicised though certainly no
less important, was to enable Iran to hold out against Iraq - but just
barely, so that the war could continue for as long as possible. According
to retired IDF general Avraham Tamir, Defense Secretary Haig explained to
his Israeli counterpart Sharon that 'it was U.S. policy to prevent either side from
winning' (Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: 328). And indeed, as
journalists Waas and Unger describe in their colourful language, the
Administration '"tilted" back and forth between support for Iran and support for
Iraq, sometimes helping both countries simultaneously, sometimes covertly
arming one side as a corrective to unanticipated consequences of having
helped the other' (1992: 65). Arms shipments to sustain the Iranian
war effort - ranging from $500 million to $1 billion annually, depending
on the source - were handled by Israel. At the same time, the Americans
also kept promoting the Iraqi cause. This was done in a variety of ways:
by renewing diplomatic relations; by providing military intelligence; by
granting low-interest loans; by encouraging Saudi financial assistance; by
asking the Gulf states and Egypt to deliver more than $1.5 billion worth
of arms and ammunition; and, finally, by allowing over $5 billion of U.S.
credit - partly guaranteed by the Agriculture Department - to be covertly
(and possibly fraudulently) used for Iraqi purchases of U.S. machinery and
technology with military and nuclear applications (Business Week,
13 July 1992; Waas and Unger 1992). To facilitate payments for the war
effort, it was suggested in 1984 that Bechtel construct a multibillion
dollar pipeline from Kirkuk to the Jordanian port of Aqaba, so that Iraqi
oil exports could bypass the hazards of the Gulf. The undertaking was
endorsed by CIA Director William Casey, but apparently that wasn't enough.
The main risk was Israel, whose war planes could have easily blown the
project out of operation. And so Bechtel lined up an impressive battery of
friends, including Swiss oil magnate Bruce Rappoport, U.S. Attorney
General Edwin Meese, and National Security Adviser Robert McFarlane, whose
role was to make sure such an attack wouldn't happen. Rappoport, with his
reputed CIA connections and long-termfriendship with Israeli Prime
Minister Shimon Peres, managed to obtain a written promise, signed by
Peres, that Israel wouldn't mess with the pipeline; this in return for an
overall premium of about $650 million, payable in ten equal annual
instalments, which would then be partly diverted to Peres' Labour Party.
To further secure the arrangement, Peres was willing to freeze in a
'salvage fund' $400 million out of the U.S. military aid to Israel, and
Meese and McFarlane laboured to arrange that the scheme be approved by the
Overseas Private Investment Corporation (Business Week, 22 February
1988; Frenkel 1991: 30-4).
The Oil-Arms
Bust
The project, however, never took off, perhaps because the flows of
petrodollars and weapondollars were themselves beginning to recede. In
1980, the volume of Middle East oil production started to decline, and in
1982 prices followed suit. The combined result was a steep drop in the
region's oil revenues - from $197 billion in 1980 to a mere $52 billion by
1986, according to UN data. And given the intimate link from oil exports
to arms imports, the consequences for the weapon makers were dire. 'We're all down now to
nibbling crumbs', professed a frustrated U.S. defence executive
during the 1985 Paris air show: 'The damn oil boom has gone and there is not much
money around any more' (cited in Ferrari et al. 1987: 4-5). As of
themselves, these developments are not entirely surprising. First, high
oil prices induced greater energy efficiency, substitution to alternative
sources, and further exploration and output by non-OPEC producers. Second,
diversification by Saudi Arabia and Kuwait into downstream operations
brought them into conflict with the companies. And finally, the Iran-Iraq
War, previously a major source of 'risk' and 'scarcity', was no longer
viewed as a threat for Western oil supplies.
Indeed, in this sense, the situation during the early 1980s
differed from the one prevailing after the 1973 Arab-Israeli War. In the
earlier conflict, the anti-Israel alliance of the Arab countries lent
credibility to their 'oil weapon' and the threat of future shortages. By
the 1980s, however, the OPEC front was no longer united and two important
members of the cartel were themselves military foes. The disturbances
occurring in the Persian Gulf, particularly the so-called 'tanker war' and
attacks on oil installations, made the oil market nervous and perhaps
exerted a positive influence on prices. Yet rivalry prevailed instead of
cooperation, and with no end in sight to the hostilities, the likelihood
of restoring OPEC's earlier cohesion seemed remote. In this respect, the
overriding need of both Iran and Iraq for new weapons and ammunition only
made things worse, since it forced both to stretch production to the
limit, creating a gushing flow of 'distress oil'. [23
footnote] And so, from a certain point onward, the Iran-Iraq War
turned from a blessing to a curse. Instead of boosting prices, it now
caused them to fall, creating a rather taxing environment for both
OPEC and the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition.
Given the gravity of the situation, Saudi Arabia agreed to provide
a 'cushion' for OPEC's other members, selling its oil at the cartel's
official price and absorbing the demand shortfall. The cost, though,
mounted quickly. The kingdom had to reduce its output from 9.8 million
barrels a day in 1981, to 6.5 million in 1982 and, finally, to a mere 3.2
million in 1985, but even that failed to stabilise spot prices (OPEC
Annual). Eventually, the Saudis bailed out, and as their production rose,
panic ensued and the price collapsed even further.
In 1986, with the price of crude oil heading below $10 a barrel for
the first time since 1973, the Petro-Core's rate of return once again
dropped below the big economy's average (Figures 5.7 and
5.8). And as the Middle East found itself entering a new 'danger
zone', Vice-President Bush found himself on a mission to Riyadh, with the
task of openly asking the Saudis to reconsider their actions and
reinstate lower levels of production. Bush insisted that the government of
the United States was 'fundamentally, irrevocably committed'to maintaining the
free flow of oil, and that 'the interest in the United States is bound to be cheap energy
prices'. However, the Vice-President also emphasised that '[there] is some point at
which the national security interests of the United States say, "Hey, we
must have a strong, viable domestic interest"' (New York
Times, 7 April 1986).
The other reason for the Administration's concern for oil was the
armament market. Defence procurement at home started to level off after
having soared for a decade. And yet, military shipments to the Middle
East, which could have partly compensated for the shortfall, were now
drying up for lack of petrodollars. Worse still, as Table 5.3
shows, competitors from other countries were now winning market share from
American companies. In contrast to the period until the late 1970s, when
the market was more or less under the thumb of the two superpowers, since
the early 1980s suppliers from Europe and the developing world were making
significant headway. By the end of the 1980s, these contenders saw their
combined market share rise to more than 50 per cent, double its level a
decade earlier; the share of U.S. suppliers, on the other hand, dropped to
18%, down from 48%. [24
footnote] A large part of this decline was due to the fact that
U.S. arms shipments, despite considerable deregulation under Reagan, were
still partly subjugated to 'foreign policy' considerations, whereas in
other countries they were by now completely commercialised. And so, with
the Iranian market having been lost to scandal, and with sales to Iraq
forbidden by government decree, U.S.-based firms could only watch and see
their competitors stepping in to fill the void. The lost opportunity was
immense. The Iran-Iraq War, which dragged on for much of the 1980s, turned
out to be the most expensive conflict since Vietnam, with the belligerent
countries spending over $400 billion to fight each other. And yet, save
for covert shipments, the profits from this gold mine were going not to
U.S. firms, but to their rivals. [25
footnote]
Table 5.3 Arms Exports to the
Middle East
SOURCE: U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency (1975 Edition, p.
70; 1980 Edition, p. 160; 1985 Edition, p. 134; 1998 Edition, p. 174);
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Statistical
Abstract of the United States, 1991, Table 550, p. 340.
The 1990-91 Gulf
War
With so much at stake, it was once again time for the U.S.
Administration to hype the Persian Gulf as a 'vital national interest'. In a speech given
in 1987, Secretary of Defense Weinberger reminded his audience that the
Middle East still contained 70% of the world's proven reserves. The role
of the United States, he said, was to assure the region was secure, stable
and, above all, free from Soviet influence and intervention. According to
Weinberger's strict guidelines, the American military was practically
prevented from intervening in any conflict short of a world war. The only
exception was the Middle East, where direct military intrusion was deemed
warranted (Gold 1993: 76). From a realist perspective, though, this new
emphasis sounded a bit odd. Indeed, according to the analysis laid out in
Gold (1993: 75), during Reagan's second term in office the region had
become strategically less important to the U.S. 'national
interest'. For one, the Soviet Union, locked into a losing war of
attrition in Afghanistan, was no longer perceived as marching toward the
Strait of Hormuz. Furthermore, although the Middle East still contained
much of the world's reserves, the expansion of non-OPEC output, greater
conservation, and new energy-saving technologies, have together made this
oil less important than before. And, finally, the experience of the
Iran-Iraq War suggested that regional conflicts could go on with oil
supplies remaining cheap and plentiful. But then, these very developments,
which from the viewpoint of the U.S. 'national interest' were supposedly
all good, spelled serious trouble for the Weapondollar-Petrodollar
Coalition. And so the escalation began.
Warming Up
Attempts to bolster U.S. military presence in the region began in
1984, when Washington tried to persuade the Persian Gulf emirates to allow
the installation of American bases on their soil. The latter refused, but
in 1986, when an Iraqi Mirage fighter hit an American frigate, Washington
responded by sending aircraft carriers into the region. The Iranians
retaliated by littering the Gulf with naval mines, to which the United
States answered with mine sweepers. And, so, in 1986, when Vice-President
Bush was on his mission to Saudi Arabia in an effort to raise oil prices
by peaceful means, the U.S. military was already well on its way toward
direct involvement in the region, a trajectory which would four years
later culminate in Operation Desert Storm.
The first direct target was Libya's ruler, Muammar Qaddafi, who was
increasingly blamed for fostering international terrorism. A Sixth Fleet
armada of more than 45 warships, including three aircraft carriers with
over 200 planes, was dispatched in March 1986 toward the renegade state.
The official reason was to 'enforce the principle of freedom of the seas' against
Qaddafi's unwarranted extension of Libya's territorial waters to the 32nd
parallel. But as U.S. administration officials later acknowledged, the
real purpose of the operation, code-named Prairie Fire, was rather
different. The plan was to provoke a military response by Libya, against
which U.S. forces would retaliate with escalating counter-strikes,
including the destruction of the Libyan air force and bombing raids on the
country's oil fields. Qaddafi, however, failed to pick up the bait and did
not respond in any meaningful way (Montreal Gazette, 29 March 1986;
Time, 7 April 1986). A new opportunity arose a month later, after a
terrorist attack on a West Berlin discotheque ended with numerous injuries
and one dead American soldier. The blame for the attack was immediately
put on Libya and the fleet was sent once again toward Qaddafi's 'line of
death'. But the Libyan ruler, to whom Reagan referred as the 'mad dog of
the Middle East', held his fire and the military exchange was limited
(Time, 21 April 1986). Incidentally, the Syrians, who were also
blamed for being involved in the West German bombing, came out against
'U.S. aggression' in Libya, and there were increasing reports about
heightening Israeli-Syrian tensions (Time, 26 May 1986). The
attempted escalation continued, when in August, information leaked by the
Administration to the Wall Street Journal suggested that the United
States and Libya were again 'on a collision course' (Time, 13 October 1986).
This policy of confrontation was presented as part of a new,
stronger U.S. stand against radical Middle East regimes. In 1987, however,
Reagan abruptly abandoned the Libyan cause, shifting his focus back to the
Persian Gulf. The official reason was again the Soviets. The 'tanker war'
in the Gulf, which since 1980 had already accounted for over 300 damaged
oil vessels, was suddenly made into a top priority after the Kuwaitis
requested U.S. protection for their tankers. Initially, the Administration
appeared reluctant, but then quickly reversed its stance once the Kuwaitis
turned to the Kremlin (Gold 1993: 79-104; Darwish and Alexander 1991:
244-5). The real story, however, was more complicated. Since the beginning
of 1986, the Administration was voicing open concerns that Iran was
getting the upper hand in its six-year war with Iraq. But, then, in
November of that year, the Iran-Contra Affair began to unravel, suggesting
that part of the credit for Iran's success must go to the U.S.
Administration itself. Revelations that Reagan was both condemning and
supplying Tehran forced Washington to reiterate its anti-Khomeini stance,
and the Kuwaiti request provided the right pretext. The Seventh Fleet
assumed the role of protecting Kuwaiti tankers, and before long found
itself attacking Iranian oil installations and exchanging fire with
Iranian forces.
The intensified conflict and growing U.S. involvement drew the more
moderate Gulf states deeper into the militarisation process. Countries
such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Oman and the United Arab Emirates were now
looking to buy more U.S.-made weapons, which the White House was only too
happy to supply. [26
footnote] The Congress, though, being far less forthcoming than the
Administration, managed to block several large deals, forcing the Gulf
states to look for alternative sources. [27
footnote] The biggest setback for the U.S. companies was the 1988
'deal of the century', in which the United Kingdomagreed to supply Saudi
Arabia with $25 billion worth of military hardware, construction and
technical support over the next two decades (Business Week, 12
September 1988). The end of the Iran-Iraq War in 1988 opened new business
opportunities for companies which could help rebuild the war-shattered
infrastructures of the two countries. The scope of the work was
substantial - estimated at the time in excess of $200 billion - but then
here too U.S. corporations found themselves facing stiff competition from
non-U.S. rivals (Business Week, 29 August 1988).
'Danger Zone'
The Bush presidency, which began in 1989, provided continuity for
the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition in Washington. Some of the
Coalition's representatives were by now gone, but their successors were in
most cases equally aware of the oil and armament interests at stake. These
included, in addition to oil millionaire George Bush, people such as
Nicolas Brady, who previously ran Dillon, Read & Company when it was
controlled by Bechtel, and who was now nominated Treasury Secretary;
Robert Mosbacher, an oil businessman who now became Secretary of Commerce;
and James Baker, a lawyer with deep ties to the oil business, who
previously served under Ford and Reagan, and was now made Secretary of
State (during the 1990s, Mosbacher and Baker returned to the private
sector as special consultants to the energy giant Enron). Bush also wanted
John Tower to become Secretary of Defense, but the former senator, who
acted as retainer for five defence contractors, failed the conformation
hearings. Eventually, the post went to Richard Cheney, a strong supporter
of 'Star Wars' and the Contra rebels, who would later become Vice
President under George Bush's son.
The Middle East situation, however, remained precarious for the
Coalition. Despite the Administration's loyalty and its greater military
involvement in the region, the price of oil did not recover significantly,
the Petro-Core's rate of return was still in the 'danger zone', and demand
for foreign weapons was stuck in the doldrums. The gravity of the
situation was succinctly summarised in February 1990 by the head of
CENTCOM, General Norman Schwarzkopf. Appearing in front of the Senate
Armed-Forces Committee, Schwarzkopf, whose father had previously set up
the dreaded Iranian SAVAK, explained the crucial and growing significance
of Middle East oil. The region, he warned his audience, had 13 ongoing
conflicts, and if any one of them were to develop into a fullfledged war,
the consequences for the West could be dire. Despite this danger, though,
he strongly recommended that the United States increase its military
exports to the region in order to match disturbing advances made by
foreign competitors. On the day of Schwarzkopf's speech, a 'prime Pentagon
source' suggested to the Wall Street Journal that the
Administration, now that the East-West conflict was over, should divert
funds from defending Europe to protecting Saudi Arabia (cited in Frenkel
1991: 9-13). The background for these pressures was succinctly summarised
two months later by an unnamed Pentagon official:
"No one knows
what to do over here. The [Soviet] threat has melted down on us, and what
else do we have? The navy's been going to the Hill to talk about the
threat of the Indian navy in the Indian Ocean. Some people are talking
about the threat of the Colombian drug cartels. But we can't keep a $300
billion budget afloat on that stuff. There is only one place that will do
us as a threat: Iraq." (cited in Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: 354-5)
And, indeed, a month later Saddam Hussein finally made his move,
beginning to threaten his Gulf neighbours with the dire consequences of
their oil policies.
After the end of the Iran-Iraq War, Hussein found himself between a
rock and a hard place. His country was devastated, overburdened by $80
billion in foreign debt, and deprived of petrodollars. In order to rebuild
his economy and army, he demanded that the Gulf states, which in his view
benefited from Iraq fighting the fundamentalist threat for them, should
now foot up the bill, forgiving their Iraqi loans and providing him with
even more funds (Darwish and Alexander 1991: Chs 9-11). In parallel, he
also insisted that OPEC should get its act together by reducing output and
raising prices. Needless to say, neither policy sat well with his
neighbours. First, they had no desire to help refortify Iraq only to see
its claws eventually turned against them (Darwish and Alexander 1991:
256-65; Frenkel 1991: 15-18). And, second, some of the Gulf states,
particularly Saudi Arabia and Kuwait, were by now sufficiently diversified
into downstream operations to benefit from more moderate prices
(Business Week, 3 July 1988, 21 January 1991). Seeing that the
differences could not be settled peacefully, Hussein eventually decided to
take Kuwait over. On paper at least, this would have helped him kill two
birds with one stone - enlarging his own fiefdom while simultaneously
limiting overproduction by 'merger'. The only problem was that there was a
much bigger picture to consider, and here Hussein's calculations proved
fatally wrong.
By July, with the build-up of Iraqi forces along the Kuwaiti border
becoming all too evident, the United States deployed several combat ships
on joint manoeuvres with the United Arab Emirates. But except for these
drills its message to Iraq was ambiguous and, at times, even encouraging.
To learn more on the American position, Hussein summoned the U.S.
ambassador, April Glaspie. In the interview which was held on 25 July, a
week before the invasion, Hussein explained his grievances against Kuwait,
noting quite explicitly that Iraq intended to 'take one by one' its
disregarded rights. Glaspie replied that the dispute was an internal Arab
matter on which the United States had 'no position', and that she had a 'direct instruction from the
President to seek better relations with Iraq'. When Hussein
mentioned his demand that OPEC push the price of oil over $25 per barrel,
Glaspie chose to respond that there were also many Americans who would
like to see the price go above that level. On 28 July, Bush reportedly
sent a message to Hussein that the use of force against Kuwait was
unacceptable, but three days later his Under-Secretary of State Kelly said
to reporters that the United States had 'no defence treaties with any Gulf countries'.
On 1 August, despite the CIA's conclusion that an Iraqi attack was
imminent, the United States still failed to voice any explicit warning
(Darwish and Alexander 1991: 267-75).
Back on Top
The American stance changed drastically, however, once the Iraqis
began crossing the Kuwaiti border on 2 August. Three days after the
invasion, Defense Secretary Cheney and General Schwarzkopf convinced the
Saudi royal family that their kingdom was Hussein's next target - a most
implausible presumption by all counts as U.S. officials later admitted -
persuading them to invite the deployment of 'infidel' forces on their
land, something which until then the Saudis always managed to avoid
(Woodward 1991: Ch. 19). During the following months, Hussein apparently
attempted to seek a face-saving diplomatic solution, but to no avail. For
the Americans, the opportunities offered by open confrontation were simply
too great to give up.
And, indeed, the consequences of the war were highly beneficial for
the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition. The initial rise in the price of
crude oil - from around $14 per barrel in 1990 to near $40 just before the
onset of Operation Desert Storm - helped pull the Petro-Core's
profitability above the big economy's average (see Figures 5.7 and
5.8). In 1991, the price per barrel declined to an average of $22
(which, incidentally, was not much below what Hussein demanded on the eve
of his invasion), but that was still sufficient to keep the Petro-Core out
of the 'danger zone'. [28
footnote] The price revival raised Middle East oil revenues, and
although their level was still far below that of the early 1980s, the
anxiety created by the war, particularly in Saudi Arabia and the adjacent
sheikdoms, caused them to nervously convert more of their petrodollars
into weapondollars.
And this time, the main beneficiaries were U.S. firms, whose
exports to the region in the two years following the war jumped by 45%,
according to the U.S. Department of Commerce. Part of the increase was in
the export of civilian goods and services, mainly to Kuwait. During its
short occupation, the Iraqi army engaged in systematic plunder, stealing
according to some estimates $20-50 billion worth of Kuwaiti property. In
addition, it also left behind war damages whose repair cost was projected
at $100 billion. Perhaps not surprisingly, some of the largest
reconstruction contracts went to Bechtel, beginning with a $1 billion task
of extinguishing the 650 oil fires ignited by the retreating Iraqi army,
and continuing with the multibillion-dollar job of restoring oil
production, repairing refineries and rebuilding damaged infrastructure
(Business Week, 18 February 1991, 6 March 1991, 11 March 1991, 17
February 1992; Fortune, 25 March 1991). Most of the export
increase, however, was in the category of military goods and services,
which rose dramatically to reinstate the United States once again as the
region's prime supplier (see Table 5.3).
On 6 March 1991, while addressing a joint session of Congress after
the Iraqi surrender, George Bush exclaimed that 'it would be tragic if the
nations of the Middle East and Persian Gulf were now, in the wake of the
war, to embark on a new arms race' (New York Times, 7 March
1991). Then, on 30 May, he went further, calling the major arms-exporting
countries to establish guidelines 'for restraints on destabilizing transfers of
conventional arms' to the Middle East (New York Times, 30
March 1991). In parallel, however, the President also insisted it was
'time to put an end to
micro-management of foreign and security assistance programs,
micro-management that humiliates our friends and allies and hamstrings our
diplomacy' (New York Times, 7 March 1991). To help erase
some of the traces of such 'micro-management', in which both he and Ronald
Reagan were explicitly implicated, Bush granted pardon in 1992 to six key
figures in the Iran-Contra Affair, including a pre-emptive one to former
Defense Secretary Casper Weinberger whose trial was just about to begin.
Then, in line with the eternal principles of free enterprise, the
Administration instructed American embassies to expand their assistance to
U.S.-based military contractors, and even proposed to alter the 1968 Arms
Exports Control Act, so that the Export-Import Bank could guarantee $1
billion in loan-financing for U.S. arms exports (U.S. Congress 1991: 21;
New York Times 18 March 1991). [29
footnote] True to the time-honoured strategy of 'stabilisation
through military exports', Bush proposed in January of 1991, while the
Gulf War was still going, that the United States sell Saudi Arabia over
$20 billion worth of armament - a deal so large that the Administration
eventually had to 'slice' it into smaller pieces, for easier Congressional
digestion (U.S. Congress 1991: 21).
And, so, by 1990, after a decade of losing ground to rival sellers,
the United States, helped by falling exports fromthe former Soviet Union,
was oncemore the largest weapon exporter to developing countries. The
American comeback was especially pronounced in the Middle East - so much
so that it prompted British officials to openly complain that the United
States was 'monopolizing' the region's arms trade (The Independent,
13 December 1992). The Gulf War also helped reinstate the primacy of
petroleum companies vis-à-vis their host countries. The previous political
arrangement, with OPEC in the spotlight and the oil in the background, no
longer seemed to work. Despite the region's militarisation, producing
countries were increasingly acting at cross purposes, with Saudi Arabia,
the companies' principal ally, unable to bring them back into line. And
so, here too the war helped put things back in order. The region's most
important suppliers - notably Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and surrounding
sheikdoms - were now signatories to defence treaties with the United
States and Britain, which effectively subordinated their oil policies to
U.S. dictates. Iraq was put out of circulation by UN sanctions, and with
Iran still isolated, the risk of glut was significantly limited. On the
surface, then, the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition looked ready to
roll. But in fact, this was to be its last victory, at least for the time
being. After the Gulf War, the 'danger zone' opened up once more, with oil
profits falling below the average. And yet, this time around there was no
new energy conflict to pull these profits back up.
The Demise of
the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition
The New
Breadth Order
Compared with the 1970s and 1980s, the 1990s were far less
hospitable to weapon dealers and oil profiteers. During the earlier
period, dominant capital in the developed countries found itself well
extended within its respective envelopes, its breadth potential being
restricted by the post-war legacy of statism, by antitrust policies, and
by capital controls. Given these barriers, differential accumulation
concentrated mainly on stagflationary depth, whose main promulgators and
principal beneficiaries were members of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar
Coalition. But this constellation was inherently temporary. For most large
firms, stagflation was a stopgap measure, to be abandoned once the
pendulum swung back to breadth.
The basic conditions for renewed breadth were laid down in the late
1980s. Soviet economic liberalisation, the abandonment of import
substitutions in much of the developing world, and the retreat of statism
in the industrialised countries, worked to dismantle barriers on capital
mobility and ease antitrust sentiments. And with controls falling apart,
large firms were now more than eager to break their last, national
'envelope', moving toward integrated global ownership. [30
footnote] The differential prize was substantial. For the winners,
gains from cross-border mergers and acquisitions, bolstered and
replenished by green-field prospects in the developing countries, were far
greater than the increasingly risky benefits from war profits and
stagflationary redistribution. And as the world began shifting back to
breadth, the symptoms of depth receded rapidly: world inflation fell to
less than 5% in 1999, down from over 30% at the beginning of the decade;
international hostilities were actively curtailed, with the number of
major conflicts falling to 25 in 1997, down from 36 in 1989; and military
budgets the world over came under the axe, dropping by over one-third in
real terms from their peak in the late 1980s. [31
footnote]
The Middle East, an epicentre for conflict and stagflation during
the global depth phase, was greatly affected by this renewed breadth. The
disintegration of the Soviet Union and the end of the Cold War robbed
local wars of their international raison d'être. In parallel, the
petrodollar boom, which earlier fuelled the region's military arsenals,
turned into bust, making conflict difficult to sustain. The decline in oil
prices and revenues also had dramatic domestic implications. Until the
early 1980s, the oil bonanza helped local rulers tranquillise their
domestic populations with a cocktail of large public spending and
extensive internal security budgets. But with the peace blitz pulling the
rug from under oil prices, the technique became expensive. According to
World Bank data, GNP per capita in the Middle East and North Africa,
measured in constant U.S. dollars, fell to 35% of the world's average in
1998, down from 42% in 1979, with the predicament being particularly
severe in the Gulf countries, where per capita income, again measured in
constant dollars, dropped by as much as 50-80%. Starved of revenues,
governments were forced to cut their budgets, and as spending declined,
internal opposition, particularly from 'Islamic fundamentalism',
intensified. The region's autocratic rulers were of course willing to
fight such opposition nail and tooth, even with less resources. And yet,
here too, global circumstances, particularly the ideological shift from
statism to liberalism, put them on the defensive, weakening their
self-confidence and compromising their resolve. And so, before long, many
of them found themselves between a rock and a hard place. No longer awash
with petrodollars, unable to pit one superpower against the other, and
bogged down by domestic instability, their only way to survive was to
accept U.S. protection. Those who refused, such as Libya and Iran, were
doomed to isolation, whereas those opting for independent 'initiatives',
such as Iraq with its invasion of Kuwait, risked severe punishment.
Israel, too, was caught largely off guard. Although its dominant
capital was not directly dependent on oil, its domestic depth regime of
militarised stagflation was intimately linked to the regional cycle of
energy conflicts. Until the late 1980s, the local ruling class was still
struggling to retain this regime, although its resolve, like that of other
elites in the region, was severely weakened. The immediate reasons were
the Palestinian Intifida, the collapse of the world market for arms
exports, and increasing domestic macroeconomic instability, which, as we
saw in Chapter 4, have together contributed to a massive differential
accumulation crisis. The more fundamental reason, though, was the growing
realisation that depth had come to an end. Global conditions now required
a new mechanism of accumulation, and possibly the restructuring of
dominant capital itself.
The most important change in mechanism was a shift away from
military conflict. On the surface, the transition seemed perplexing, even
surreal. George Bush, a Weapondollar-Petrodollar loyalist, who only a few
years earlier was busy promoting the Iran-Iraq conflict, and who had just
completed a classic sting operation against Iraq, was now announcing in
great fanfare the onset of a 'new world order' built on Middle East peace. Israeli and
Arab leaders responded quickly, switching from bullets to business as if
they had no animosity to overcome. And before the world could catch its
breath, Prime Minister Rabin and Chairman Arafat were shaking hands on the
White House lawn, celebrating the mutual recognition of their embattled
nations.
The basic preconditions for this transition, though, were taking
shape far from the troubled sands of the region, in the boardrooms of the
world's largest corporations. Much like during the earlier transition from
breadth to depth, the current swing from depth back to breadth was also
accompanied by a fundamental power shift within dominant capital.
Whereas earlier, the transition strengthened the 'angry elements' of the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition, this time, it was civilian business
which took the lead.
The Last
Supper (Almost)
The Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition of course didn't give up
easily. During the 1990s, it spent much time and effort trying to regroup
and consolidate through corporate amalgamation, usually with full
government backing. The consequence of this process was a massive
centralisation in both the armament and oil sectors, culminating in the
emergence of huge corporate 'clusters', illustrated in Table 5.4.
Table 5.4 The World's Largest
Weaponry and Oil Companies, 1999 (with major acquisitions/mergers during
the 1990s)
SOURCE: Defense News (various issues); Financial Times
Survey of Aerospace, 24 July 2000; Fortune; Moody's (Online);
Charles Grant, 'A Survey of the Global Defence Industry', The
Economist, 14 June 1997; newspaper clippings.
In the armament sector, amalgamation was kick-started in 1993 when
U.S. Defense Secretary Les Aspin invited the CEOs of the country's leading
contractors to their 'Last Supper'. Military spending, he said, was poised
for further declines, and with less orders to go around, the Clinton
Administration wished to see its suppliers start merging. To speed up the
process, the government relaxed its antitrust stance, and even reimbursed
the merged firms for their amalgamation costs. It also declared that, when
it came to military exports, foreign policy objectives would from now on
take a back seat to profit considerations (Grant 1997). And so, over the
next few years, the companies were busy buying each other out, until, in
2000, there emerged a clear pack of five leaders: Lockheed Martin (which
now combined Lockheed, Martin Marietta, Loral, and much of the military
lines of General Dynamics and General Electric); Boeing (which acquired
McDonnell Douglas and Rockwell's aerospace defence electronics); Raytheon
(which added E-Systems and the military arms of Texas Instruments and
Hughes); General Dynamics (which sold many of its original military lines
only to buy others from Teledyne, Lucent, GTE and Gulfstream); and
Northrop Grumman (which combined Northrop and Grumman, along with the
military lines of LTV and Westinghouse). Of the 16 companies which we used
as a proxy for the Arma- Core, only 8 remained as independent contractors;
the rest were either taken over or divested of defence holdings
altogether.
And once centralisation had run its course in the U.S., the focus
shifted to Europe, where in a matter of three years it gave rise to three
Pan-European giants: BAE, EADS and Thomson. The European process was
particularly noteworthy, since it involved cross-border amalgamation and
significant privatisation in countries with strong statist traditions. The
biggest amalgamate was created by UK-based British Aerospace (BAE), which
took over Marconi from GEC plc., bought AES from U.S.-based Lockheed
Martin, and acquired a minority stake in the Swedish-based Saab. In
parallel, BAE also entered into various joint ventures with the newly
formed European Aeronautic Defence and Space Company, or EADS. The latter
conglomerate was created in 2000, by pooling together the various defence
interests of DASA (formerly DaimlerChrysler Aerospace), France's
Aerospaciale and Lagardère, and Spain's Arianespace. When EADS was formed,
its largest shareholders were DaimlerChrysler, Lagardère, and the
governments of France and Spain, but over 27% of its stock were already
publicly listed, with further privatisation to come. The third European
giant, Thomson-CSF, was owned jointly by the French government, Alcatel,
and Dassault Industries, with another onethird of the stocks trading
freely on the market and additional privatisation in the pipeline.
The global oil sector went through similar centralisation. Unlike
in defence, the process here was not openly promoted by governments,
although few of the mergers faced any serious antitrust opposition. The
major deals of the 1990s, listed in Table 5.4, included the
acquisition of Mobil by Exxon to create Exxon- Mobil, of Amoco and
Atlantic Richfield by BP, now named BP-Amoco, and of Fina and Elf
Aquitaine by Total, now called Total Fina Elf. [32
footnote]
The differential financial consequences of these mergers were
dramatic. The world's six largest oil firms listed in Table 5.4 had 1999
sales of $513 billion, 25% more than the six companies making the
Petro-Core in its peak year of 1990; and $27 billion in net profit, 24%
above the Petro-Core's record of 1980. In the armament sector the picture
was more mixed. In 1999, the world's seven largest defence contractors
listed in the table had $84.4 billion in defence revenues, compared with
$61.3 billion for the 16 Arma-Core firms in their peak year of 1985. Their
net profit, however, was only $2.5 billion, compared with the Arma-Core's
record of $9.9 billion in 1989.
The problem for the large oil and armament companies here was that,
by now, they controlled much of their universe, and that this universe was
either growing slowly (as in the case of oil), or contracting (in the case
of defence). Under these circumstances, internal breadth through
amalgamation was inherently self-limiting, so that in this sense,
government encouragement of greater centralisation merely pushed the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition further toward its sectoral envelope.
Beyond that point, continued differential accumulation for the Coalition
depended on renewed conflict and stagflation boosting up overall profits.
And yet, from the viewpoint of dominant capital as a whole, that
route was unattractive, and in fact dangerous. By the early 1990s,
civilian business offered much better ways to beat the average.
Furthermore, the new civilian avenues required relative openness and
stability, the very opposite of the conflict and stagflation with which
the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition fuelled the earlier depth regime.
Figure 5.9 Share of Standard
& Poor's 500 Market Capitalisation
SOURCE: McGraw-Hill (Online). DRI codes: SPAEROMV, SPOILDMV,
SPOILIMV for Weaponry and Oil, SPHTECHMV for 'High-Tech'.
The greater lure of civilian business is illustrated in Figure
5.9. The chart contrasts two series, each measuring the market
capitalisation of a given corporate cluster, expressed as a share of the
Standard & Poor's 500 (S&P 500), a widely used index for the
largest firms listed in the United States. [33
footnote] The first series denotes the proportionate share of 26
leading aerospace and petroleum companies, a proxy for what earlier
constituted the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition. The second series,
focusing on civilian business, measures the comparable share of 54 leading
'high-technology' companies. The focus on relative market capitalisation
is indicative of how global investors view the future course of
differential accumulation, and where profit growth is expected to
be the fastest. From this perspective, the inverse movement of the two
series points to a dramatic change occurring during the 1990s. Until the
late 1980s, dominant capital was still under the fading eclipse of the
Weapondollar- Petrodollar Coalition, with its representatives included in
the chart accounting for close to 11% of the S&P 500 total
capitalisation. The 'hightechnology' sector was relatively small, with
less than 8% of the total. Over the next decade, however, the situation
has totally reversed. The armament and oil firms saw their relative share
drop to about 5% of the S&P 500, whereas that of the 'high-technology'
companies soared to a peak of nearly 34%. In 2000, 'high-technology'
stocks collapsed, but even after the calamity, the sector's capitalisation
was still three times larger than that of armament and oil combined. This
picture is of course somewhat skewed by the much richer valuation of
'high-technology' companies, whose relative earning growth has so far
lagged behind their differential capitalisation. Nonetheless, it seems
evident that the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition has lost its earlier
primacy, and that the centre of gravity, at least for now, has shifted
back to civilian business.
The fading power of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition was
mirrored in the Middle East. During the 1990s, attempts to kick-start a
new 'energy conflict' seemed to go nowhere. Every summer, tensions in the
region would rise, sometimes pulling oil prices up with them, but never
enough to build up momentum. During the early part of the decade, the main
excuse were Iraqi ceasefire violations, to which the United States and
Britain eagerly retaliated with aircraft and missile attacks. The
situation again looked on the brink of war, when in September 1994,
Washington announced that Saddam Hussein had dispatched an 80,000-strong
force toward the Kuwaiti border, prompting President Clinton to send
60,000 soldiers and 600 aircraft back to the Gulf. But like Muammar
Qaddafi before him, the Iraqi ruler preferred to ignore the 'smart'
missiles and held his fire. Since then, numerous other enemies have
appeared on the scene, from a nuclear Iran, to the Lebanese Shiites, to
Islamic terrorism. And yet, despite the hyped rhetoric and ongoing
hostilities - including the recent U.S.-led attack on Afghanistan - none
of this has so far managed to significantly affect the price of oil.
The Gulf War was the Last Supper of the Weapondollar-Petrodollar
Coalition, at least for the time being. During the 1990s, dominant capital
as a whole was increasingly seeking cross-border expansion, a process
which required tranquillity, not turmoil. Given that military conflict
endangered such expansion, and that high energy prices threatened to choke
the green-field potential of 'emerging markets', the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition found itself increasingly isolated. And
with depth giving way to breadth, it is perhaps not surprising that the
'national interest' itself was conveniently modified. As Business
Week put it, 'The
President has recognised that, in the post-cold-war era, getting global
contracts for U.S. business is a matter of national security' (23
April 1994).
This neoliberal version of the national interest was eventually
challenged by the 2001 attack on the Twin Towers and the Pentagon. Before
turning to the present crossroad, however, we need to first travel through
the transnational breadth phase of the 1990s.
-
- – Jonathan Nitzan & Shimshon Bichler
The Global Political Economy of Israel by Jonathan
Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler Pluto Press LONDON • STERLING,
VIRGINIA First published 2002 by Pluto Press 345 Archway Road,
London N6 5AA and 22883 Quicksilver Drive, Sterling, VA
20166-2012, USA http://www.plutobooks.com/ Copyright © Jonathan
Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler 2002 The right of Jonathan Nitzan and
Shimshon Bichler to be identified as the authors of this work has
been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and
Patents Act 1988. British Library Cataloguing in Publication
Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the
British Library ISBN 0 7453 1676 X hardback ISBN 0 7453 1675 1
paperback
See review, at Monthly Review
Please note: All books referred to are listed in the
Bibliography of The Global Political Economy of Israel.
Footnotes:
- We ignore here parallel listings of subcontracting, foreign
military sales, and contracts awarded by NASA and the Department
of Energy. These contracts are significant, but their recipients
tended to be the same as the DoD's prime contractors
- Excluded from the sample is Hughes
Aircraft which, as a privately held firm until 1986, did not
publish financial reports. Also omitted are General Motors, which
entered the Arma-Core only in 1986 after acquiring Hughes
Aircraft; LTV, which filed for bankruptcy protection in 1986; and
Tenneco, whose annual contract awards fluctuated widely
- In the electronics industry, for
instance, General Electric embarked on a major restructuring
programme which, over the 1981-87 period, saw the company acquire
some 338 business and product lines, while divesting 232 others
(Business Week, 16 March 1987). The process, whose main
goal was to move away from markets dominated by the Japanese,
included the 1985 acquisition of RCA, particularly for its defence
business, and the 1986 swap of GE's consumer electronic lines for
Thomson's medical equipment unit (Time, 23 December 1985; 3
August 1987). In 1992, General Electric sold its defence
electronics unit to Martin Marietta, but in turn became a major
shareholder of the latter company (Business Week, 7
December 1992). In the aircraft industry, Lockheed left commercial
aviation altogether, after its entanglement with the L-1011
airliner brought it to near bankruptcy. Similarly, McDonnell
Douglas, which was initially created in 1967 when McDonnell
absorbed Douglas as a means of diversifying into non-defence
activity, never made any money from civilian aircraft, and, in
1991, entered into a tentative agreement to sell 40% of its
civilian unit to Taiwan Aerospace (Business Week, 14
February 1983; 23 May 1988; 2 December 1991). The deal failed to
go through, and McDonnell Douglas was eventually absorbed by
Boeing, which sought to bolster its position against Europe's
Airbus consortium. Similar retreats plagued the automobile
industry, where pressures from Japanese competition pushed
U.S.-based firms back into defence-related activity. The most
publicised move here was General Motors' acquisition of EDS and
Hughes Aircraft, which during the 1980s turned the 'car company'
into one of the country's top ten defence contractors
- Symbolically, if (MS) is overall
military sales, (MSd) is domestic sales, (MSe) is
export sales, and (v) is the ratio between the export and
domestic markups, then the relative contribution of military
exports to military-related profit (RC) is given by the
following expression:
RC = (v · MSe) / (v · MSe + MSd)
- Earlier pre-crisis studies are also not
without fault. For example, in his work Multinational Oil,
Jacoby (1974: 245-7) showed that the large oil companies suffered
a significant decline in their foreign profitability, which he
attributed to increased competition since the mid-1950s. Jacoby's
methodology and implications are questionable, however. First,
much of the decline of international profits in the 1950s was
rooted not in more intense competition, but in higher royalties to
host countries. Second, since the royalties were debited as
foreign taxes against the oil companies' domestic operations,
focusing only on foreign operations serves to conceal the
compensating increase in domestic after-tax earnings. Indeed, as
Blair (1976: 193-203, 294-320) demonstrated, the decrease in the
companies' global rate of return was far smaller than the one
recorded in their operations abroad. Furthermore, global
profitability started to rise again in the early 1960s and, by the
early 1970s, was already far higher than in the early 1950s
- Our own notion of 'politicisation' here is completely different from
the realist concept of 'petro-political cycles' developed by Wilson (1987).
According to the latter, during a sellers' market, producing
countries are able to politicise the market in order to raise
prices. During a buyers' market, on the other hand, Western
countries are content letting competition reign, so as to bring
prices down. Clearly, this focus on states does not allow for a
transnational political coalition between the U.S.
government, OPEC, the oil majors and the large armament
contractors, along the lines developed in this chapter
- The extent of the companies' control
during that time is well illustrated by their ability to contain
the threat of oil glut throughout the Great Depression. During the
1930s, the Iraqi Petroleum Company - a joint venture between
British Petroleum, Royal Dutch/Shell, CFP, Exxon, Mobil, and 'Mr
5%', Calouste Gulbenkian - exercised a Veblenian policy of
'watchful waiting' throughout much of its 1928 Red Line Agreement
regions. In Iraq, for example, the company actively utilised only
1% of its concession; in Qatar it delayed production until 1950,
some 18 years after the first exploration; and in Syria, it
drilled shallow holes in order to fulfil its concession charter
without producing any output (Blair 1976: 80-6)
- Indeed, many policy initiatives were
cancelled solely due to opposition from the large companies. For
example, during the Second World War, the large firms objected to
the Petroleum Reserve Corporation taking control over their joint
Saudi holdings, much as they opposed the Anglo-American Oil
Agreement and the Saudi Arabian Pipeline. The big companies also
refused to allow independent companies more than a symbolic share
in the 1953 Iranian Consortium; they objected the 1970 Shultz
Report which suggested to substitute tariffs for the dated system
of import quotas; and they ignored the Administration's request to
accommodate Libyan demands for a higher price. As a result, none
of these policies and suggestions came to fruition (see Blair
1976: 220-30; Krasner 1978a: 190-205; and Turner 1983: 40-7,
152-4)
- Conceptually, we should have contrasted
arms imports with the region's net income from oil exports,
rather than with the overall value of its oil output. The latter
measure is broader, including, in addition to net export income,
also production costs and the value of domestically consumed oil.
Furthermore, our own measure here is imputed as the product of
physical output multiplied by the average spot price, rather than
measuring the actual revenues received. We use this proxy
nonetheless because it is available consistently for the entire
period, and since it correlates very closely with various net
income series which are unfortunately available for only shorter
sub-periods
- Some of these connections involved the
Texas oil associations of Vice-President Johnson, the southwestern
and international oil affiliations of Secretary of the Navy
Connally, the Rockefeller links of Secretary of State Dillon, and
the long-term business partnership between CIA director McCone and
the Bechtel family (Engler 1977: 57-8; McCartney 1989)
- According to former Israeli ambassador
to the United States, Abba Eban, many in the State Department were
convinced of Israel's military superiority and ability to win a
'crushing victory' already in the 1950s (Eban 1977: 185). After
the 1967 War, IDF generals such as Ezer Weitzman, Benjamin Peled
and Yitzhak Rabin, admitted quite openly that Nasser had presented
no real danger. Ten days before the war, a secret CIA report
delivered to Johnson accurately predicted an Israeli victory
within six days. Some U.S. officials who hoped to avert a war
communicated these assessments directly to Jordan and Egypt and,
indeed, until the last moment, Nasser still hoped for a diplomatic
resolution (Cockburn and Cockburn 1991: 140-54)
- While official crude prices had not
changed, fuel prices for Western consumers rose, thus boosting the
profits of the oil companies while undermining them elsewhere in
the economy
- On Nixon's campaigns, see Sampson
(1975: 205-6) and Sampson (1977: 151-2, 195). On Kissinger, see
Barnet (1983: 178-9). Representatives of Rockefeller's Chase
Manhattan were involved in the network of activists around Nixon's
career, and some of them accepted key posts in his administration.
Paul Volker, for example, was made Under Secretary of the Treasury
for Monetary Affairs; John Letty became Assistant Secretary of the
Treasury; and Charles Fiero became Director of the Office of
Foreign Direct Investment in the Commerce Department (Barnet and
Müller 1974: 251; Turner 1983: 105)
- During the 1962-66 period, Israel's
annual weapon imports averaged $107 million. After the 1967 War,
with the United States replacing France as the main supplier, the
average almost tripled to $290 during 1967-69, and in 1970-72,
with the Nixon Doctrine starting to kick in, it rose further to
$550 (unpublished data from Israel Central Bureau of Statistics,
courtesy of Reuven Graff)
- Allegations that the U.S. government
was promoting higher prices as a primary means of funding U.S.
arms deliveries to the Shah were put forward on the CBS programme
Sixty Minutes (3 May 1980). Kissinger, though, declined to
comment (Chan 1980: 244). Kissinger was also closely associated
with Rockefeller's Chase Manhattan, and it is not far fetched to
assume he also contemplated the benefit for the bank from higher
petrodollar deposits (Ha'aretz, 2 January 1981)
- Israel was compensated for its
withdrawal from the Sinai peninsula with two new airfields in the
Negev desert worth $2.2 billion, and a 'reorganisation' package of
15 F-15 and 75 F-16 aircraft valued at $1.9 billion. The Egyptians
were allowed to purchase 50 F-5 fighter aircraft worth $400
billion (with an option to buy more advanced ones later), and the
Saudis bought another 60 F-15s worth $2.5 billion
(Ha'aretz, 3 April 1983). Cyrus Vance, who participated in
the negotiations as Carter's Secretary of State, was later
nominated a director of General Dynamics, one of the deal's
principal winners
- The allegations about a deal between
Iran and the Reagan campaign headquarters were first made by Gary
Sick and others (New York Times, 15 April 1991; Sick 1991)
- Earlier, Haig served as Nixon's Deputy
Assistant for National Security Affairs, as well as the White
House Chief of Staff, but his leverage was now much stronger.
Shiff and Yaari (1984) allege that it was he who gave Israel's
Defence Minister Sharon the 'green light' to invade Lebanon in
1982. United Technology, to which Haig later returned as a special
consultant, exported helicopters and aircraft engines to the
Middle East. Haig was able to persuade the Israeli government to
install United Technology's engines in its proposed Lavi aircraft
- although the IDF preferred the alternative engines made by
General Electric. Eventually General Electric came out on top.
While the Lavi got cancelled, the Israeli air force, with the help
of hefty bribes to IDF Brigadier General Rami Dotan, decided to
equip its F-16 fighters with GE engines
- During the 1980s, the Bechtel family
owned about two-fifths of the company's shares, with the remainder
spread among the firm's senior managers. The company had to be
excluded from our statistical analysis due to lack of publicly
available data
- Supplying arms and equipment to the
U.S. army during the Second World War, John McCone and his partner
Steven Bechtel Sr. managed to earn in only a few years over $100
million on an investment of less than $400,000; certainly a
remarkable achievement, even by the loose standards of war
profiteering (McCartney 1989: 70)
- Perhaps the largest bribe was the $200
million paid to Saudi officials in return for the $3.4 billion
contract to build the new airport in Riyadh. The earliest covert
operation involved the Syrian coup of 1949, after the Syrian
government raised obstacles to the construction by Bechtel of a
Saudi-Syrian pipeline
- The petroleum sector was a double
winner under Reagan. Whereas over the 1960-80 period its effective
tax rate rose from 11 to 29% on an average annual profit of less
than $7 billion, during the next five years earnings rose to $27
billion annually, while effective taxation dropped to 18%
(computed from the U.S. Department of Commerce through McGraw-Hill
Online)
- Spending on the war was partly financed
by foreign assistance, with Khomeini supported by both Syria and
Libya, and Iraq allegedly receiving $30-60 billion in cash and
replacement oil from Saudi Arabia and other Gulf states
(Business Week, 4 June 1985; Stockholm International Peace
Research Institute 1987: 303). This aid, however, was hardly
sufficient for the task at hand, leaving the two countries no
choice but to prime the pump
- During the 1990s, U.S. producers
recovered the lost ground, although according to realist thinking
they should have done far better. Indeed, with their country being
the world's sole hegemon now that the Soviet Union was no more,
what was to prevent them from kicking their competitors completely
out of the picture? But then, the question itself is misguided. By
now, U.S., European and Japanese contractors have grown
increasingly intertwined through complicated supply chains and
transnational cross-ownership, so that their 'state' allegiance
was not always obvious. Also, and as we shall see at the end of
the chapter, the U.S. 'national interest' was itself starting to
shift from weaponry to other business, making competition over
Middle East arms contracts seem less important
- Some estimates suggest that Iraq
imported about $40 billion worth of arms during the period from
1980 to 1986, while Iran's foreign purchases amounted to $30
billion. The overall stake of covert U.S. shipments in these
totals must have been limited. The prime suppliers for the war
were based in France, the United Kingdom, West Germany, Italy,
South Africa, the Soviet Union, China, North and South Korea,
Vietnam, Israel, Taiwan and Brazil (Business Week, 29
December 1986; for a full list of the 52 known participating
countries, see Stockholm International Peace Research Institute
1987: Table 7.8, pp. 204-5). According to Jane's Defence
Weekly, Iraq even supplied Iran, reselling to the latter
through private dealers heavy weapons previously captured in the
fighting (reported in Stockholm International Peace Research
Institute 1987: 307). For detailed accounts of the arming of Iraq
during and after the Iran-Iraq War, see Darwish and Alexander
(1991: Chs 4-6) and Timmerman (1991)
- In 1988, the Administration suggested
increasing U.S. arms exports by $3.3 billion, to a level exceeding
$15 billion - with proposed shipments worth $3.6 billion to
Israel, $2.7 billion to Egypt, $950 million to Saudi Arabia, and
$1.3 billion to other Middle Eastern countries (New York
Times, 2 May 1988). This proposal did not prevent Secretary of
State Shultz from declaring in front of the U.N. General Assembly
only a few weeks later that 'developing countries must help reduce the
international tension and ease the arms race' (New York
Times, 14 May 1988)
- In 1985, the Congress refused to
approve the sale to Saudi Arabia of 40 advanced McDonnell Douglas
F-15 aircraft and, in 1986, blocked the sale of 800 General
Dynamics Stinger missiles. In 1988, the U.S. Senate voted to deny
a Kuwaiti request for Hughes (GM) Maverick missiles and also
forbade the sale of Stinger missiles to Oman (New York
Times, 13 May 1988; Time, 25 July 1988)
- Many oil executives actually felt
relieved by the more moderate prices, which were high enough for
differential profitability but not for 'conspiracy theory'. Just
to be on the safe side, though, some oil companies decided during
the last quarter of 1990 to write off part of their higher profits
against the cost of 'future environmental regulations' (Business
Week, 11 February 1991)
- Government support was not limited to
defence contracts, of course. For example, both President Bush and
his Secretary of State Mosbacher did not hesitate to intervene
personally on behalf of AT&T, when Saudi Arabia appeared to
prefer European contractors for its $8.1 billion plan to expand
the kingdom's telephone network (Business Week, 18 February
1991). The new Clinton Administration kept up the pressure and
AT&T eventually won the contract
- For instance, of the 599 regulatory
changes recorded by the World Investment Report during the
first half of the 1990s, 95% were aimed at liberalising capital
controls. Similarly, the number of bilateral investment treaties
had risen to 1,330 by 1996, up from fewer than 400 in the early
1990s, with 88% of the changes aimed at increased liberalisation
and incentives for foreign investment (United Nations Conference
on Trade and Development 1997: 18-19)
- Data are calculated from International
Monetary Fund (Annual), the Stockholm International Peace Research
Institute (Annual), and the U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament
Agency (Annual)
- As these lines were written, Chevron
and Texaco announced their intention to merge, a union which would
create the world's fifth largest oil company in terms of sales
- The index comprises leading companies
listed on the New York Stock Exchange, American Stock Exchange and
Nasdaq. Companies are usually leaders in their field and their
contribution to the index are weighed by market value. In contrast
to Fortune 500 companies whose 'home base' must be the United
States, S&P 500 firms could be based anywhere, provided their
shares are listed in the United States
|
|