Table of Contents:
- Capitalism and War
- The Rise and Demise of Military Keynesianism
- The Globalization of Ownership
- The New Wars
- The New Order of Capital
- Energy Conflicts and Differential Profits
- The Primacy of Prices
- Sweet Inflation
- Cheap Wars
1. Capitalism and War
The
recent flurry of wars—from Afghanistan and Iraq to Gaza and Lebanon
—has revived talk of Imperialism, Military Keynesianism and the
Military-Industrial Complex. Capitalism, many radicals have long
argued, needs war. It needs it in order to expand its geographical
reach; it needs it in order to open up new markets; it needs it in
order to gain access to cheap raw materials; and it needs it to placate
opposition at home and pacify rebellious populations abroad.[1]
The
common perception is that war serves to boost the economy. According to
this argument, military conflict—and high military spending in
preparation for such conflict—generates overall growth and helps reduce
unemployment. This feature of military spending turns it into an
effective fiscal tool. In years of slack, the government can embark on
Military Keynesianism, increase its spending on weapons and pull the
economy out of recession.
Over
the longer haul, military expenditures are said to undermine the
peaceful, civilian outlook of liberal regimes. Spending on the military
boosts the business interests of the large armament corporations,
hardens the outlook of the security apparatus and emboldens the top
army brass. Together, these groups become increasingly fused in an
invisible, yet powerful, Military-Industrial Complex—a complex that
gradually comes to dominates policy and pushes society toward foreign
aggression and military adventurism.
2. The Rise and Demise of Military Keynesianism
Theories
of Military Keynesianism and the Military-Industrial Complex became
popular after the Second World War, and perhaps for a good reason. The
prospect of military demobilization, particularly in the United States
, seemed alarming. The U.S. elite remembered vividly how soaring
military spending had pulled the world out of the Great Depression, and
it feared that falling military budgets would reverse this process. If
that were to happen, the expectation was that business would tumble,
unemployment would soar, and the legitimacy of free-market capitalism
would again be called into question.
Seeking
to avert this prospect, in 1950 the U.S. National Security Council
drafted a top-secret document, NSC-68. The document, which was
declassified only in 1977, explicitly called on the government to use
higher military spending as a way of preventing such an outcome.[2]
NSC-68
marked the birth of Military Keynesianism. In the decades that
followed, military expenditures seem to have worked as the document
envisaged. The basic process is illustrated in Figure 1.
The graph shows the relationship between U.S. economic growth and the
country’s military spending. The thin line plots the annual rate of
economic growth against the right scale. The thick line shows the level
of military spending, expressed as a share of GDP and plotted against
the logarithmic left scale.[3] Both series are smoothed as 10-year moving averages to emphasize their long term tendencies.
The
data show a co-movement of the two series, particularly since the
1930s. The rise in military spending in preparation for the Second
World War coincided with a massive economic boom. Military spending had
risen to 43 percent of GDP by 1944 and averaged 20 percent of GDP
during the 1940s. This rise was accompanied by soaring economic growth,
with annual rates peaking at 18 percent in 1942 and averaging 6 percent
during the 1940s (the peak levels of the early 1940s cannot be seen in
the chart due to the smoothing of the series).
After
the war, military spending began to trend downward, but remained at
very high levels for the next couple of decades. The adoption of
Military Keynesianism, along with the wars in Korea and Vietnam ,
helped keep military expenditures at 12 percent of GDP during the 1950s
and at 10 percent during the 1960s. Economic growth during this period
averaged over 4 percent—lower than in the Second World War, but rapid
enough to sustain the buoyancy of American capitalism and the
confidence of its capitalists.
Both
big business and organized labor supported this set up. The large
corporate groups saw military spending as an acceptable and even
desirable form of government intervention. At the aggregate level,
these expenditures helped counteract the threat of recession at home
and offset the loss of civilian markets to European and Japanese
competitors—yet without undermining the sanctity of private ownership
and free enterprise. At the disaggregate level, many large firms
received lucrative contracts from the Pentagon, handouts that even the
staunchest free marketers found difficult to refuse.
The
large unions endorsed Military Keynesianism for different reasons. They
agreed to stay out of domestic politics and international relations, to
accept high military expenditures, and to minimize strikes in order to
keep the industrial peace. In return, they received job security, high
wages and the promise of ever-rising standards of living.
The consensus was aptly summarized in 1971 by President Nixon, who pronounced that ‘we are all Keynesians now.’
But
that was the peak. By the early 1970s, the Keynesian Coalition of big
business and organized labor started to unravel, Military Keynesianism
began to wither and the welfare-warfare state commenced its long
decline.
3. The Globalization of Ownership
Underlying
the rise and demise of Military Keynesianism was an epochal reversal in
the spatial nature of ownership—a U-turn from gradual de-globalization
in the first half of the century to massive globalization in the second
half.
Until
the 1950s, the ownership of capital, in the United States and
elsewhere, was retreating into its national cocoons. The statistical
footprints of the process are clear. In 1900, the ratio of foreign-held
assets to world GDP reached a peak of 19 percent. But the subsequent
turmoil of two world wars, depression, import substitution and capital
controls have taken a heavy toll. Foreign ownership ties were broken or
frozen, and the ratio of foreign-held assets to world GDP fell
continuously, reaching a mere 6 percent in 1960. At the trough of the
process, the accumulation of capital was conducted largely within
national boundaries.
This
decline ended in the early 1970s. Capital again broke through its
national envelope, and as neoliberalism and deregulation gained
momentum foreign ownership started to rise. The ratio of foreign-held
assets to world GDP increased exponentially, doubling every decade: it
rose to 25 percent in 1980, climbed to 50 percent in 1990, and reached
over 90 percent by 2000.[4]
The
effect on profit of this reversal has been dramatic. U.S.-based firms
now receive roughly one third of their earnings from their foreign
subsidiaries, up from 5 percent in the 1950s—a six-fold increase.
This
reversal in the global pattern of ownership fundamentally altered the
power structure and institutions of capitalism. With capital bought and
sold on a world scale and profits increasingly earned outside the
country, capital accumulation became less and less reliant on domestic
sales. With less emphasis on local activity, Keynesian policies grew
out of fashion. And with Keynesianism on the decline, the
business-labor accord started to unravel.
The
welfare state, previously seen as a bulwark against communism, became a
burden. Labor was no longer likely to revolt—particularly with jobs
being shipped to ‘emerging markets’ and with union membership on the
decline. Furthermore, capitalists were no longer fearful of recession.
On the contrary, they often encouraged it as a means of disciplining
workers, reducing wages and reversing the hard-won social gains of
working people.
The
warfare state was also coming under pressure. The turning point was the
collapse of Soviet Bloc. With only one superpower remaining, large
military budgets were now difficult to justify. In the 1990s, military
spending around the world took a nose dive, falling by as much as a
third from their all time peak in the late 1980s. As Figure 1
shows, expenditures on armaments in the United States , the world’s
largest spender, dropped to an average of 4.5 percent of GDP in the
first half of the 2000s, down from 7 percent in the 1980s.
4. The New Wars
The demise of the welfare-warfare state opened the door for the new rhetoric of neo-liberalism.
Proponents of free markets hailed the new regime for its peaceful
tendencies. Its detractors agreed—but only partly. On the one hand,
they concurred that neoliberalism, in its quest to secure free trade
and open capital flow, tries to establish political stability and
international peace. On the other hand, they faulted neoliberalism for
its invisible violence, inflicted through hyper exploitation, mass
poverty, rising inequality, economic uncertainty and human insecurity.
Both
the adherents and the critics, therefore, were surprised by the sudden
bellicosity of the early twenty-first century. Old theories of
imperialism and militarism were quickly dusted off and tucked onto
neoliberalism. Instead of productivity miracles and No Logo, analysts
started to talk about ‘new imperialism’ and ‘neoliberal wars.’
For
the most part, though, these hybrid theories are misleading. The new
conflicts of the twenty-first century—the ‘infinite wars,’ the ‘clashes
of civilization,’ the ‘new crusades’—are fundamentally different from
the ‘mass wars’ and military conflicts between states that
characterized capitalism from the nineteenth century until the end of
the Cold War. The main difference lies not so much in the military
nature of the conflicts, as in the broader role that war plays in
capitalism.
To
begin with, in a world open for business there is no need to physically
conquer new territory—not for raw materials and not for additional
markets (note that Iraqi oil production has nearly ceased since its
conquest in 2003, while its market for foreign imports, negligible to
begin with, has contracted).
The
same goes for military spending: with the share of foreign profits
soaring, there is no longer a business imperative for high military
expenditures. While U.S. military budgets have risen somewhat in the
wake of the new wars—from 3.9 percent of GDP at the end of Clinton ’s
presidency to 4.7 percent presently—this is an increase whose effect on
aggregate demand is insignificant by historical standards.
The
U.S. attacks of the 2000s also make little military sense. Countries
with proven nuclear capabilities, such as Pakistan and North Korea,
have been left alone, while others that presented no real
danger—specifically Afghanistan and Iraq—were invaded, occupied and now
tie down much of the U.S. standing army, with no end in sight.
Finally,
the televised war footing and constant talk about terrorism may have
frightened the western population. But unlike the success of
nationalist-liberal ideologies during the two world wars and the Cold
War that followed, the new rhetoric of infinite war hasn’t made the
masses fall for neoliberal capitalism.
The wars of the 2000s are indeed new. And they are new, at least in part, because capitalism itself has changed.
5. The New Order of Capital
The
central change concerns the underlying nature of capital, a
transformation that began in the late nineteenth century but became
evident only recently.
Existing
theories, anchored in the reality of the early nineteenth century,
continue to examine capital from the ‘material’ perspective of
consumption and production. Neoclassical economists anchor their
analysis in utility, while classical Marxists base it on labor time. In
contrast to these approaches, we suggest that, under modern conditions,
capital can no longer be viewed as a ‘material’ entity. As we see it,
capital represents neither neoclassical utility nor Marxist abstract
labor, but rather power—the power of its owners to shape the process of
social reproduction as a whole.
Based
on a power understanding of capital, we argue, first, that the analysis
of capitalism should focus not on capital ‘in general’ and many
capitals ‘in competition,’ but specifically on the dominant capital groups at the centre of the political economy. Second, we claim that accumulation should be understood not absolutely, but differentially—that is, in reference to the ability of dominant capital to ‘beat the average’ and increase its relative power.[5]
The implications of this power perspective are far reaching. For our purpose here, they suggest:
1. That
over time, corporate mergers, rather than economic growth, become the
main engine of differential accumulation (‘breadth’); and
2. That under certain circumstances, dominant capital can benefit greatly from inflation and stagflation (‘depth’).
In
our research we found that, over the past century, global accumulation
indeed oscillated between these two regimes of merger and stagflation.
The most recent phase, which lasted through much of the late 1980s and
1990s, was clearly one of breadth. In that period, dominant capital
benefited greatly from the opening up to corporate takeover of the
former Soviet Union and other ‘emerging markets,’ as well as from the
collapse of the welfare state and the massive privatization of
government services.
This
breadth cycle, with its emphasis on neoliberalism, deregulation, sound
finance and disinflation, came to a close at the turn of the new
millennium. The financial crisis that began in Asia and later spread to
the core markets, the crumbling of the ‘new economy’ and its scandalous
accounting practices, and talk of global terrorism and the infinite war
to defeat it, have together made capital movement look less tempting
and mergers far less promising. Furthermore, two decades of
neoliberalism have weakened pricing power, raising the specter of price
and debt deflation for the first time since the Great Depression.
Faced
with these predicaments, capitalists generally and dominant capitalists
particularly began yearning for a little dose of ‘healthy’ inflation
both to avert debt deflation and to kick-start differential
accumulation. As it turned out, the solution for their predicament—intended or otherwise—was a new ‘Energy Conflict’ in the
Middle East
(that is, a conflict related directly or indirectly to oil). Over
the past thirty-five years, these conflicts have been the prime mover
of oil prices, and oil prices have provided the spark for broad-based
inflation. It was a turnkey mechanism for triggering inflation, and it
was ready to use.
In
this sense, military conflict has come to assume a new, roundabout role
in the accumulation process. Until the 1950s and 1960s, the main impact
of military conflict worked through large military budgets which
directly boosted aggregate demand and overall profits, as well as the
income of the leading military contractors. But with the
re-globalization of ownership and the on-setting of détente, military
budgets started to contract. Initially, they fell relatively, as a
share of GDP, but since the late 1980s, they also began to drop
absolutely, in constant dollar terms. Although these expenditures still
nourish the military contractors, their direct effect on capital
accumulation has diminished significantly.
However,
military conflict as such hasn’t lost its appeal; it still has a big
impact on accumulation. The novelty is that the impact now works mostly
indirectly, through inflation, relative prices and redistribution.
6. Energy Conflicts and Differential Profits
The
key beneficiaries of this new, indirect link are the large oil
companies. The geographic centre of this process is the Middle East .
After the Vietnam War, the Middle East has become the hot spot of
global conflict, with obvious corollaries for the price of oil. The
relationship between these conflicts and the differential profits of
the oil companies, however, has received little or no attention.
The
reason for this neglect is not difficult to see. Most analyses of
Middle-East conflict and oil are situated in the disciplinary
intersection of ‘international relations’ and ‘international
economics.’ Their basic reasoning boils down to a struggle among states
over raw materials. On the one hand, there are the industrialized
countries that need cheap oil in order to sustain their growth and
expanded reproduction. On the other hand there are the countries of the
Middle East , organized through OPEC, whose intention is to extract
from the process as much rent as they can. This broad conflict is
complicated by various factors: for example, inter-state rivalry—say
between the United States and the Soviet Union (previously) and Europe
and Asia (presently); religious and ethnic hostilities in the Middle
East itself; or the interests of various sectors and capitalist
fractions in the industrialized countries.
In
this polemic of high politics and resource economics, few have bothered
to break through the aggregate front, fewer have done empirical work,
and almost no one has dealt with the question of how exactly
accumulation by the oil companies fits into the picture. Figure 2 offers a glimpse into what is missing from the story.
The chart shows the history of differential accumulation by the
‘Petro-Core’ of leading oil companies—specifically: BP, Chevron, Exxon,
Mobil, Royal-Dutch/Shell and Texaco.[6]
Each
bar in the figure measures the difference between the rate of return on
equity of these companies and the average rate of return on equity of
the Fortune 500 benchmark (with the result expressed as a percent of
the Fortune 500 average). The grey bars show years of differential
accumulation; that is, years in which the leading oil companies beat
the average with a higher rate of return. The black bars show periods
of differential decumulation; that is, years in which the
leading oil companies trailed the average. For reasons that will become
apparent in a moment, these latter periods signal ‘danger’ in the
Middle East . Finally, the explosion signs show ‘Energy
Conflicts’—namely, conflicts that were related, directly or indirectly,
to oil.[7] The figure exhibits three related patterns, all remarkable in their persistence:
– First, every energy conflict in the
Middle East
was preceded by a danger zone, in which the oil companies suffered differential decumulation.
– Second, every energy conflict was followed by a period during which the oil companies beat the average.
– And, third, with only one exception in 1996-7, the oil companies never managed to beat the average without an Energy Conflict first taking place.[8]
Furthermore,
this pattern fits into the larger processes of breadth and depth. The
figure points to three distinct periods, each characterized by a
different regime of differential accumulation, and each led by a
different faction within dominant capital.
During
the depth era of the 1970s and early 1980s, differential accumulation
was fuelled by stagflation and driven by conflict. The leading faction
within dominant capital was the Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition of
large armament and oil firms. In this context, the oil companies
managed to beat the average comfortably, with only occasional setbacks
which were quickly corrected by Middle East conflicts.
During
the breadth period of the late 1980s and 1990s, merger replaced
inflation as the main engine of differential accumulation. The oil and
armament companies lost their primacy to a ‘new economy’ coalition led
by civilian high-tech companies. Neoliberal rhetoric replaced the lingo
of welfare-warfare state, conflicts in the Middle East grew fewer and
farther between, and the oil companies commonly trailed the average.
Events
over the past few years suggest that this second period may have come
to an end, with the ebbing of the merger boom and the return to primacy
of the Weaponodollar-Petrodollar Coalition. The
latter coalition, whose fortunes had dwindled since the stagflationary
bonanza of the 1970s and early 1980s, has come back with a vengeance.
Having helped re-install the Bush family in the White House, the
coalition started looking for new enemies and was only too happy to
exploit the opportunity offered by the ‘new Pearl Harbor ’ of September
11.[9]
The
argument and statistical patterns presented here were first articulated
in the late 1980s, further developed in the mid-1990s, and most
recently updated in 2006.[10] However, the last few observations in Figure 2
are new, and they suggest a quantitative departure from past patterns.
Until the late 1990s, the differential performance of the oil companies
oscillated between 50 percent above or below the Fortune 500.
Recently, though, the scale changed. During the period of 2000-2005,
the world’s four leading oil companies earned US $338 billion in net
profit—one third of a trillion—representing an average rate of return of 20 percent, nearly twice the Fortune 500’s.
7. The Primacy of Prices
The link that connects Middle-East conflicts and differential profitability is the price of oil. This link is illustrated in Figure 3.
The thick line in the chart shows the percent share of all listed oil
companies in global corporate profit. The thin line shows the
‘relative’ price of crude oil, computed by dividing the dollar price
per barrel by the U.S. consumer price index, and lagged one year (reported
corporate earnings represent the moving sum of the past four quarters;
the full impact on profit of a change in the price of oil therefore is
felt only after a year).
The correlation between the two series is extremely tight.[11]
This statistical fact points to the immense importance that prices have
come to play in the process of accumulation. In this particular chart,
the tight correlation makes much of the media discussion and learned
analyses of the oil arena redundant. In order to know the reported
differential profits of the oil companies a year from now, you don’t
need to speculate about Peak Oil, about rising demand from China , or
about the coming heat waves in Europe . This type of guesswork,
although interesting for other purposes, is unnecessary here. The only
thing you need to know is the current price of oil.
To
illustrate: the official data are not yet in, but we already know that,
over the past 12 months, the price of oil averaged roughly US $65 in
2002 prices. The correlation in the chart suggests that, a year from
now, the reported global profit share of the oil companies will hover
around 15 percent.
Now, let’s backtrack and examine the history presented in Figure 3.
The data show that, during the oil crisis of the 1970s and early 1980s,
the cost of crude petroleum shot through the roof. In 1979 a barrel of
oil cost over US $90 in today’s prices. During those happy
stagflationary times, the oil companies pocketed nearly 20 percent of
all global profits. But as differential accumulation moved into breadth
and mergers picked up, inflation fell and oil prices dropped even
faster. The oil companies’ global share of profit collapsed, reaching a
mere 3 percent by the end of Clinton ’s presidency.
The
reversal came with the new millennium and the Bush presidency. With the
2001 invasion of Afghanistan, the Middle East entered a protracted
period of war, oil prices have risen to US $65-75, and the share of the
oil companies in global profit—although not yet at historical highs—is
moving higher and higher.
How
big are the gains of the oil companies? During the five-year period
from August 2001 to July 2006, the average net income of the global oil
sector amounted to US $108 billion per annum. This figure compares with
an annual profit of only US $34 billion in the year from August 1999 to
July 2000—a jump of US $75 billion if we round the numbers.
How
much did it cost to generate this jump in profits? For argument’s sake,
let’s assume that since 2000 the entire increase in the price of
oil—and therefore the whole increase in oil profits—was due to the new
Energy Conflicts in the Middle East . Assume further that so far the
U.S. government has spent on its Afghanistan-Iraq operation the annual
equivalent of 1 percent of its GDP—roughly US $100 billion a year.
These
assumptions, although simplistic and inaccurate, indicate the overall
magnitudes involved: the war costs US $100 billion a year and it
generates an extra US $75 billion in annual oil profits. In other
words, for every US $1 the U.S. government spends on the wars, the
owners of the oil companies earn an additional US ˘75 in net profit.
Clearly,
such phenomenal cost-benefit ratios can be generated only indirectly.
And that is perhaps one of the important features of the new wars: a
fairly modest increase in military spending brings about massive
changes in prices and distribution—changes that go beyond the immediate
arena of the conflict, and whose magnitude can match and even exceed
the military budget itself.
8. Sweet Inflation
As
noted earlier, the new wars came as the long breadth phase of
differential accumulation was winding down. The immediate beneficiaries
were the arms contractors and the oil companies of the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar Coalition. But gradually, as global
differential accumulation shifted from breadth to depth, the gains
spread to dominant capital as a whole.
Figure 4
vividly illustrates this process for the United States . The thin line
in the graph plots the rate of inflation, measured as the annual rate
of change of the consumer price index. The thick line is a ratio
between profits and wages. It measures the ratio of the earnings per
share of the S&P 500 (the largest publicly traded corporations
listed in the United States , which could be taken as a proxy for
dominant capital) to the hourly wage rate in manufacturing.
Movements
in this latter ratio indicate redistribution. When the index rises, it
means that the profits of dominant capital rise faster (or fall more
slowly) than the wage rate. When the index falls it suggests an
opposite process—namely, that the profits of dominant capital fall
faster (or rise more slowly) than wages.
As
the chart shows, in late 2000, inflation started falling, and in 2002
it reached 1 percent—a postwar low. The decline was accompanied by a
massive drop in the ratio of profit to wages, which fell by 55 percent
from its 2000 peak. In the wake of these developments, the Federal
Reserve Board Chairman, Alan Greenspan, warned of an ‘unwelcome
substantial fall in inflation,’ and was encouraged by leading
financiers to ‘go for higher inflation.’[12]
These deflationary warnings came in April 2003, after the
U.S.
had already invaded
Iraq
. Our own view at the time was rather different. In January 2003, just before the invasion, we wrote:
[…]
if oil prices continue to rise, inflation will most likely follow, the
spectre of deflation will be removed and the large companies could
sound a big sigh of relief. For these companies there would also be an
icing on the cake. Inflation usually works to redistribute income from
labour to capital and from small firms to larger ones. It will
therefore make the leading companies better off relatively, if not
absolutely.[13]
And
indeed, Greenspan didn’t have to work too hard. The new wars have done
the job for him. The neo-conservatives sent their army to the Middle
East , the price of oil soared, and inflation—although hesitant at
first—eventually started to follow.
The
distributional consequences weren’t lost on investors and workers.
While wages remained flat, profits—particularly those earned by
dominant capital—surged. As a result, the ratio of profit to wages
climbed rapidly—rising 250 percent since 2001 and sending the overall
share of profit in GDP to its highest level since data began to be
collated in 1929.
The
huge distributional impact of a small increase in inflation is
symptomatic of the new order. During the welfare-warfare state,
inflation usually involved a wage-price spiral that worked to limit the
differential increases in profits. For instance, a 4 percent increase
in prices typically would be accompanied by a rise in wages—say, of 3
percent. As a result, the markup ratio of sales to wages would increase
by 1 percent, generating a relatively modest rise in profits. The
situation now is very different. Workers in the United Stares are
locked in global competition with workers in China, India and other
‘emerging markets,’ which means that wages do not rise—and sometimes
even fall—in the midst of price inflation. In this context, a 4 percent
inflation translates to a 4 percent increase in the markup and to a far
larger increase in profits.
All
in all, then, the new wars are definitely cheap. For a minimal cost,
they stir up inflation and generate large increases in profits. But
cheap wars have another side to them. They are hard to win.
9. Cheap Wars
The
idea of a mass, ‘voluntary’ army was born out of the French Revolution.
The new soldiers turned out to be cheaper and more loyal than
mercenaries, and they fought well. However, the masses needed to be
educated so that they could read the newspapers and follow the
propaganda—hence the birth of compulsory ‘elementary’ schooling. Later
on, the proles started to demand additional perks. They wanted culture,
insurance, pensions and veteran benefits. In the 1910s, the elites
cheated them. They sent the masses to be butchered by the millions in
the trenches of World War I, and then abandoned those who returned as
veterans. This experience raised the ante. In the early 1940s, the
citizens-soldiers had to be offered a whole welfare state, so that they
would be willing to get butchered, again, in the Second World War. What
initially looked like ‘soldiers for free’ turned out to be a rather
expensive way of fighting wars.
The
last expensive war was Vietnam . With neoliberal globalization
replacing the welfare-warfare state, there was no longer a need for
mass armies with high overhead. Instead, the capitalists started to
invest in ‘smart weapons’ that could be operated by high-school
dropouts and cause plenty of damage. They abandoned the draft in favor
of purely professional armies—partly governmental, partly private.
A
similar process has taken place in Israel . During the 1970s, in the
hay days of the Israeli welfare-warfare economy, military spending
amounted to 25 percent of GDP, the draft included most Jewish citizens
(excluding the ultra-orthodox), and the government spent heavily on
social services.
But
with the breadth regime of the late 1980s and 1990s, Israeli
capitalists became decreasingly dependent on the war economy. Israel
began its reconciliation with its neighboring Arab states, and the
military was both reduced and transformed. Military spending dropped to
6 percent of GDP, and many military activities were privatized. The
duration of military service has been shortened, and fewer get drafted.
In parallel, the welfare state has been progressively dismantled, with
education, public health care and other social services consistently
eroding. Hundreds of thousands of guest workers have been brought in,
and the labor unions have been reduced to token institutions.
The consequences of this process are illustrated in Figure 5.
The chart contrasts the average monthly wage rate with the Tel-Aviv
stock price index (both expressed in constant prices and rebased for
comparison purposes, with January 1980=100).
The
figure shows that, until the early 1990s, the fortunes of workers and
capitalists moved more or less in tandem. But with the onslaught of the
breadth regime, their roads parted. During the 1990s and early 2000s,
wages have hardly increased, while capital gains have risen to the
stratosphere.
Israeli
reservists, who were called to fight in the unfolding war, probably
have not seen this graph, but the reality behind it is certainly
familiar to them. They know about deteriorating social services, about
job insecurity, about overly expensive housing, about the loss of open
spaces. They know that getting wounded in a war is a bad deal that
yields meager compensation. Most importantly, they know that the elite
that sends them to fight doesn’t really care about them.
These
sentiments are quite explicit and appear regularly in the press. The
following is a typical report of the difficulties faced by reserve
soldiers:
Defense
Minister Amir Peretz has refused to use a law allowing IDF reservists
called up for service recently to enjoy an exemption on fines and
interest associated with debts they incur during their call-up
period. […] [The reservists] are furious after discovering they
are still required to pay the fines and interest even though they were
unable to issue payments on time because they were called up. […] ‘The
reservists are forgotten, the way they always forget us,’ said one of
the [reservists organization’s] leaders, Alex Minkovsky. ‘We're calling
on the social-minded Defense Minister Amir Peretz to wake up and do
something. We’re flooded by inquiries of reservists who are suffering
crises on a daily basis.’[14]
Dominant
capital has no such complaints. As it turns out, a day before Defense
Minister Peretz refused to heed the reservists’ plea, his government
privatized the country’s oil refineries for US $800 million. In an
interview, the winning bidder, Tzadik Bino, sounded almost embarrassed:
The
state should not have privatized the refineries, and neither should it
have privatized El-Al [the national airline], Bezeq [the national phone
company] and Magen David Adom [the emergency medical service]. […] The
next stage would be to privatize the IDF. […] We are still fighting for
our existence, and it doesn’t pay to transfer strategic assets to
private hands.[15]
The
old warfare-welfare state was dominated by charismatic figure heads,
‘leaders’ such as Churchill, de Gaulle and Ben Gurion who seemed
removed from any ‘particular’ interests. By contrast, the neoliberal
state tends to be populated by retainers—many of them corrupt and
criminal—like Bush, Chirac, Berlusconi, Sharon, Netanyahu and Olmert,
who don’t even try to hide their true loyalties.
The
capitalist elite, which is served by and sustains these politicians, no
longer bears a clear national attachment. Many of Israel ’s largest
companies are owned by foreign investors and multinational companies.
Similarly, most of Israel ’s large owners—from the Recannatis, to
Fishman to Khan—have become global investors. Israel for them is merely
one of many assets in a diversified world portfolio. Unlike during the
1970s, when they had all their eggs in the same Israeli basket, now
they don’t need to worry too much about what happens in the country.
Their local holdings represent only a fraction of their investments,
and they are highly vendible.
A recent quote from the financial section of the daily Ha’aretz, written in the midst of the fighting in
Lebanon
and
Gaza
, indicates the extent to which foreign asset diversification has been accepted as natural by ‘ordinary’ investors:
Over
and above the ‘regular’ risks of emerging markets such as China ,
Brazil or Russia , Israel has a continuous security risk. […] This risk
cannot be ignored even in peace time. The global diversification of
investment therefore is not a privilege. It is a necessity. […] It
means that, in the interest of reducing risk, Israeli investors have to
permanently allocate a fixed proportion of their assets to investment
overseas. How much is ‘enough’? Until recently, the convention was 25%,
but perhaps the share of foreign assets should be raised to 50%. Our
bodies have to stay here. But why should our savings suffer the same
fate?[16]
Under
these circumstances, it is little wonder that the Israeli ‘war machine’
has lost much of its military edge. The incentive to fight for “one’s
country” when that country is so socially fractured is much
reduced—particularly when confronted with socially embedded and highly
motivated religious militias.
And so the cheap wars linger, death and destruction mount, and the profits continue to accumulate.
Jonathan Nitzan teaches political economy at
York
University
in
Toronto
. Shimshon Bichler teaches political economy at colleges and universities in
Israel
. Most of their publications are freely available from The Bichler & Nitzan Archives (http://bnarchives.net).
Endnotes
[1]
Not all radical thinkers share this view. Some argue, to the contrary,
that war and militarization, although embedded in and often caused by
the capitalist reality, are harmful to capitalism and undermine its
vitality.
[2]
United States
, National Security Council, NSC
68: United States Objectives and Programs for National Security. A
Report to the President Pursuant to the President’s Directive of
January 31, 1950. Top Secret.
Washington
DC
, 1950 (http://geobay.com/62d3c0)
[3]
A logarithmic scale has the effect of amplifying the size on the chart
of smaller values and compressing the size of larger ones. This
transformation is useful when there are very big jumps in the data –
such as during the 1940s – jumps that would otherwise make the
variations of smaller values look too miniscule to discern on the chart.
[4] Data on the ratio of foreign assets to GDP are from Maurice Obstfeld and Alan M. Taylor, Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth (
Cambridge
: Cambridge University Press, 2004), pp. 52-53, Table 2-1.
[5] These issues are articulated in Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler, ‘Dominant Capital and the New Wars,’ Journal of World Systems Research, 2004, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 255-327 (http://bnarchives.yorku.ca/1/).
[6] Due to mergers, the data in Figure 2 pertain to British
Petroleum until 1997 and to BP-Amoco since 1998; to Chevron and Texaco
until 1999 and to Chevron-Texaco since 2000; to Exxon and Mobil until
1998 and to ExxonMobil from 1999; and to Royal-Dutch/Shell throughout.
[7]
The conflicts include the 1967 Arab-Israeli conflict; the 1973
Arab-Israeli conflict; the 1979 Israeli invasion of Lebanon; the 1979
Iranian Revolution; the 1979 Soviet invasion of Afghanistan; the 1980
beginning of the Iraq-Iran War; the 1990/1 first Gulf War; the 2000
beginning of the second Intifada; the 2001 Coalition invasion
of Afghanistan; and the 2003 Coalition invasion of Iraq (whose
publicized preparation began in 2002).
[8]
Although there was no ‘official’ conflict in 1996-7, there was plenty
of violence, including an Iraqi invasion of Kurdish areas and U.S.
cruise missile attacks.
[9] In 2003, as the
Iraq
war unfolded, we wrote the following text:
Our
own view is that Middle East conflicts were integral to the power
processes of global accumulation. […] In the process, [the
Weapondollar-Petrodollar] coalition had become increasingly fused with
its ‘parent’ governments on the one hand and its OPEC ‘hosts’ on the
other, leading to a growing ‘capital-state symbiosis’ between them.
Whether or not there was ‘conspiracy’ here, and what the precise nature
of such a ‘conspiracy’ was, remains an open question. Unfortunately,
these types of issues are not the usual staple of primetime television.
Occasionally, however, the truth does come to light, albeit with a
little delay. […] Perhaps in due course someone will publish the secret
‘Exxon Papers’ or a declassified ‘NSC Report on Energy and War in the
Middle East,’ thereby opening a window into the backroom story of
Energy Conflicts in the region (‘Dominant Capital and the New Wars,’ Journal of World Systems Research, 2004, Vol. 10, No. 2, p. 313, http://bnarchives.yorku.ca/1/).
As it turned out, the relevant documents surfaced rather quickly. Less than a year after the publication of our paper, Greg
Palast uncovered the existence of two secret – and rather different –
plans for the future of Iraq ’s oil. The 2003 U.S. invasion of Iraq ,
Palast argued, reflected the conflicting strategies of two opposing
factions. The first, vocal faction, led by the neo-cons and the
Pentagon, planned to privatize Iraqi oil, flood the market and
undermine OPEC. The other faction, led by the large oil companies and
elements within the State Department, shared none of these fantasies.
It let the neo-cons finish the job of conquering Iraq , and then sent
its representatives to take control of the country’s oil production. In
the end, there was no privatization, no flooding of the market and no
undermining of OPEC – an organization of which the United States , as
the ruler of Iraq , was now a de-facto member. See Greg Palast, ‘Secret
US Plans for Iraq ’s Oil,’ BBC News, March 17, 2005 (http://geobay.com/11c057); Greg Palast, Armed Madhouse (
New York
: Dutton, 2006).
[11] The
correlation coefficient between the two monthly series measures 0.80
(out of 1) for the period since January 1974, and 0.92 for the period
since January 1979.
[12] Alan Greenspan, ‘Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan Before the Joint Economic Committee,’
U.S.
Congress, May 6, 2003; Bill Dudley and Paul McCulley, ‘Greenspan Must Go For Higher Inflation,’ Financial Times, April 23, 2003, pp. 17.
[15] Tani Goldstein, ‘Bino to Ynet: "There Was No Need to Privatize the Refineries,’ Hebrew, Ynet, August 1, 2006 (http://geobay.com/93e47c).
[16] Ami Ginsburg, ‘What Did We Learn From the First Two Weeks of the Second
Lebanon
War?’ Hebrew, Ha'aretz, July 28, 2006.
|